Taylor rule

Last updated

The Taylor rule is a monetary policy targeting rule. The rule was proposed in 1992 by American economist John B. Taylor [1] for central banks to use to stabilize economic activity by appropriately setting short-term interest rates. [2] The rule considers the federal funds rate, the price level and changes in real income. [3] The Taylor rule computes the optimal federal funds rate based on the gap between the desired (targeted) inflation rate and the actual inflation rate; and the output gap between the actual and natural output level. According to Taylor, monetary policy is stabilizing when the nominal interest rate is higher/lower than the increase/decrease in inflation. [4] Thus the Taylor rule prescribes a relatively high interest rate when actual inflation is higher than the inflation target.

Contents

In the United States, the Federal Open Market Committee controls monetary policy. The committee attempts to achieve an average inflation rate of 2% (with an equal likelihood of higher or lower inflation). The main advantage of a general targeting rule is that a central bank gains the discretion to apply multiple means to achieve the set target. [5]

The monetary policy of the Federal Reserve changed throughout the 20th century. The period between the 1960s and the 1970s is evaluated by Taylor and others as a period of poor monetary policy; the later years typically characterized as stagflation. The inflation rate was high and increasing, while interest rates were kept low. [6] Since the mid-1970s monetary targets have been used in many countries as a means to target inflation. [7] However, in the 2000s the actual interest rate in advanced economies, notably in the US, was kept below the value suggested by the Taylor rule. [8]

The Taylor rule is typically contrasted with discretionary monetary policy, which relies on the personal views of the monetary policy authorities. The Taylor rule often faces criticism due to the limited number of factors it considers.

Equation

According to Taylor's original version of the rule, the real policy interest rate should respond to divergences of actual inflation rates from target inflation rates and of actual Gross Domestic Product (GDP) from potential GDP:

In this equation, is the target short-term nominal policy interest rate (e.g. the federal funds rate in the US, the Bank of England base rate in the UK), is the rate of inflation as measured by the GDP deflator, is the desired rate of inflation, is the assumed natural/equilibrium interest rate, [9] is the natural logarithm of actual GDP, and is the natural logarithm of potential output, as determined by a linear trend. is the output gap. The approximation is used here.

Because of ,

In this equation, both and should be positive (as a rough rule of thumb, Taylor's 1993 paper proposed setting ). [10] That is, the rule produces a relatively high real interest rate (a "tight" monetary policy) when inflation is above its target or when output is above its full-employment level, in order to reduce inflationary pressure. It recommends a relatively low real interest rate ("easy" monetary policy) in the opposite situation, to stimulate output. Sometimes monetary policy goals may conflict, as in the case of stagflation, when inflation is above its target with a substantial output gap. In such a situation, a Taylor rule specifies the relative weights given to reducing inflation versus increasing output.

Principle

By specifying , the Taylor rule says that an increase in inflation by one percentage point should prompt the central bank to raise the nominal interest rate by more than one percentage point (specifically, by , the sum of the two coefficients on in the equation). Since the real interest rate is (approximately) the nominal interest rate minus inflation, stipulating implies that when inflation rises, the real interest rate should be increased. The idea that the nominal interest rate should be raised "more than one-for-one" to cool the economy when inflation increases (that is increasing the real interest rate) has been called the Taylor principle. The Taylor principle presumes a unique bounded equilibrium for inflation. If the Taylor principle is violated, then the inflation path may be unstable. [11]

History

The concept of a policy rule emerged as part of the discussion on whether monetary policy should be based on intuition/discretion. The discourse began at the beginning of the 19th century. The first formal debate forum was launched in the 1920s by the US House Committee on Banking and Currency. In the hearing on the so-called Strong bill in 1923. the conflict in the views on the monetary policy clearly appeared. New York Fed Governor Benjamin Strong Jr., supported by Professors John R. Commons and Irving Fisher, was concerned about the Fed's practices that attempted to ensure price stability. In his opinion, Federal Reserve policy regarding the price level could not guarantee long-term stability. After the death of the congressman,[ who? ] a political debate on changing the Fed's policy was suspended. The Fed was dominated at that time by Strong and his New York Reserve Bank.

After the Great Depression hit the country, policies came under debate. Irving Fisher opined, "this depression was almost wholly preventable and that it would have been prevented if Governor Strong had lived, who was conducting open-market operations with a view of bringing about stability". [12] Later on, monetarists such as Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz agreed that high inflation could be avoided if the Fed managed the quantity of money more consistently. [4]

The 1960s recession in the US was accompanied by relatively high interest rates. After the Bretton Woods agreement collapsed, policymakers focused on keeping interest rates low, which yielded the Great Inflation of 1970.

Since the mid-1970s money supply targets have been used in many countries to address inflation targets. Many advanced economies, such as the US and the UK, made their policy rates broadly consistent with the Taylor rule in the period of the Great Moderation between the mid-1980s and early 2000s. That period was characterized by limited inflation/stable prices. New Zealand went first, adopting an inflation target in 1990. The Reserve Bank of New Zealand was reformed to prioritize price stability, gaining more independence at the same time. The Bank of Canada (1991) and by 1994 the banks of Sweden, Finland, Australia, Spain, Israel and Chile were given the mandate to target inflation. [7]

Since the 2000s began the actual interest rate in advanced economies, especially in the US, was below that suggested by the Taylor rule. The deviation can be explained by the fact that central banks were supposed to mitigate the outcomes of financial busts, while intervening only given inflation expectations. Economic shocks were accompanied by lower rates. [8]

Alternative versions

Effective federal funds rate and prescriptions from alternate versions of the Taylor Rule Taylor Rule Prescriptions for Fed Funds Rate 2016.png
Effective federal funds rate and prescriptions from alternate versions of the Taylor Rule

While the Taylor principle has proven influential, debate remains about what else the rule should incorporate. According to some New Keynesian macroeconomic models, insofar as the central bank keeps inflation stable, the degree of fluctuation in output will be optimized (economists Olivier Blanchard and Jordi Gali call this property the 'divine coincidence'). In this case, the central bank does not need to take fluctuations in the output gap into account when setting interest rates (that is, it may optimally set .)

Other economists proposed adding terms to the Taylor rule to take into account financial conditions: for example, the interest rate might be raised when stock prices, housing prices, or interest rate spreads increase. Taylor offered a modified rule in 1999: that specified .

Alternative theories

The solvency rule was presented by Emiliano Brancaccio after the 2008 financial crisis. The banker follows a rule aimed to control the economy's solvency . [13] The inflation target and output gap are neglected, while the interest rate is conditional upon the solvency of workers and firms. The solvency rule was presented more as a benchmark than a mechanistic formula. [14] [15]

The McCallum rule:was offered by economist Bennett T. McCallum at the end of the 20th-century. It targets the nominal gross domestic product. He proposed that the Fed stabilize nominal GDP. The McCallum rule uses precise financial data. [16] Thus, it can overcome the problem of unobservable variables.

Market monetarism extended the idea of NGDP targeting to include level targeting. (targeting a specific amount of growth per time period, and accelerating/decelerating growth to compensate for prior periods of weakness/strength). It also introduced the concept of targeting the forecast, such that policy is set to achieve the goal rather than merely to lean in one direction or the other. One proposed mechanism for assessing the impact of policy was to establish an NGDP futures market and use it to draw upon the insights of that market to direct policy.

Empirical relevance

Although the Federal Reserve does not follow the Taylor rule, many analysts have argued that it provides a fairly accurate explanation of US monetary policy under Paul Volcker and Alan Greenspan [17] [18] and other developed economies. [19] [20] This observation has been cited by Clarida, Galí, and Gertler as a reason why inflation had remained under control and the economy had been relatively stable in most developed countries from the 1980s through the 2000s. [17] However, according to Taylor, the rule was not followed in part of the 2000s, possibly inflating the housing bubble. [21] [22] Some research has reported that households form expectations about the future path of interest rates, inflation, and unemployment in a way that is consistent with Taylor-type rules. [23]

Limitations

The Taylor rule is debated in the discourse of the rules vs. discretion. Limitations of the Taylor rule include.

Taylor highlighted that the rule should not be followed blindly: "…There will be episodes where monetary policy will need to be adjusted to deal with special factors." [3]

Criticisms

Athanasios Orphanides (2003) claimed that the Taylor rule can mislead policy makers who face real-time data. He claimed that the Taylor rule matches the US funds rate less perfectly when accounting for informational limitations and that an activist policy following the Taylor rule would have resulted in inferior macroeconomic performance during the 1970s. [25]

In 2015, "Bond King"[ clarification needed ] Bill Gross said the Taylor rule "must now be discarded into the trash bin of history", in light of tepid GDP growth in the years after 2009. [26] Gross believed that low interest rates were not the cure for decreased growth, but the source of the problem.

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Inflation</span> Devaluation of currency over a period of time

In economics, inflation is a general increase in the prices of goods and services in an economy. This is usually measured using the consumer price index (CPI). When the general price level rises, each unit of currency buys fewer goods and services; consequently, inflation corresponds to a reduction in the purchasing power of money. The opposite of CPI inflation is deflation, a decrease in the general price level of goods and services. The common measure of inflation is the inflation rate, the annualized percentage change in a general price index. As prices faced by households do not all increase at the same rate, the consumer price index (CPI) is often used for this purpose.

New Keynesian economics is a school of macroeconomics that strives to provide microeconomic foundations for Keynesian economics. It developed partly as a response to criticisms of Keynesian macroeconomics by adherents of new classical macroeconomics.

The Phillips curve is an economic model, named after Bill Phillips, that correlates reduced unemployment with increasing wages in an economy. While Phillips did not directly link employment and inflation, this was a trivial deduction from his statistical findings. Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow made the connection explicit and subsequently Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps put the theoretical structure in place.

An interest rate is the amount of interest due per period, as a proportion of the amount lent, deposited, or borrowed. The total interest on an amount lent or borrowed depends on the principal sum, the interest rate, the compounding frequency, and the length of time over which it is lent, deposited, or borrowed.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monetary policy</span> Policy of interest rates or money supply

Monetary policy is the policy adopted by the monetary authority of a nation to affect monetary and other financial conditions to accomplish broader objectives like high employment and price stability. Further purposes of a monetary policy may be to contribute to economic stability or to maintain predictable exchange rates with other currencies. Today most central banks in developed countries conduct their monetary policy within an inflation targeting framework, whereas the monetary policies of most developing countries' central banks target some kind of a fixed exchange rate system. A third monetary policy strategy, targeting the money supply, was widely followed during the 1980s, but has diminished in popularity since that, though it is still the official strategy in a number of emerging economies.

In financial mathematics and economics, the Fisher equation expresses the relationship between nominal interest rates, real interest rates, and inflation. Named after Irving Fisher, an American economist, it can be expressed as real interest rate ≈ nominal interest rate − inflation rate.

The quantity theory of money is a hypothesis within monetary economics which states that the general price level of goods and services is directly proportional to the amount of money in circulation, and that the causality runs from money to prices. This implies that the theory potentially explains inflation. It originated in the 16th century and has been proclaimed the oldest surviving theory in economics.

In economics, the Fisher effect is the tendency for nominal interest rates to change to follow the inflation rate. It is named after the economist Irving Fisher, who first observed and explained this relationship. Fisher proposed that the real interest rate is independent of monetary measures, therefore, the nominal interest rate will adjust to accommodate any changes in expected inflation.

The Mundell–Fleming model, also known as the IS-LM-BoP model, is an economic model first set forth (independently) by Robert Mundell and Marcus Fleming. The model is an extension of the IS–LM model. Whereas the traditional IS-LM model deals with economy under autarky, the Mundell–Fleming model describes a small open economy.

In macroeconomics, inflation targeting is a monetary policy where a central bank follows an explicit target for the inflation rate for the medium-term and announces this inflation target to the public. The assumption is that the best that monetary policy can do to support long-term growth of the economy is to maintain price stability, and price stability is achieved by controlling inflation. The central bank uses interest rates as its main short-term monetary instrument.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Real interest rate</span> Interest rate taking inflation into account

The real interest rate is the rate of interest an investor, saver or lender receives after allowing for inflation. It can be described more formally by the Fisher equation, which states that the real interest rate is approximately the nominal interest rate minus the inflation rate.

The monetary policy reaction function is a function that gives the value of a monetary policy tool that a central bank chooses, or is recommended to choose, in response to some indicator of economic conditions.

In monetary economics, the demand for money is the desired holding of financial assets in the form of money: that is, cash or bank deposits rather than investments. It can refer to the demand for money narrowly defined as M1, or for money in the broader sense of M2 or M3.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Great Moderation</span> Phenomenon in economies of developed nations since the mid-1980s

The Great Moderation is a period in the United States of America starting from the mid-1980s until at least 2007 characterized by the reduction in the volatility of business cycle fluctuations in developed nations compared with the decades before. It is believed to be caused by institutional and structural changes, particularly in central bank policies, in the second half of the twentieth century.

Athanasios Orphanides is a Cypriot economist who served as Governor of the Central Bank of Cyprus between 3 May 2007 to 2 May 2012 and as a member of the Governing Council of the European Central Bank between 1 January 2008 and 2 May 2012.

Market monetarism is a school of macroeconomic thought that advocates that central banks target the level of nominal income instead of inflation, unemployment, or other measures of economic activity, including in times of shocks such as the bursting of the real estate bubble in 2006, and in the financial crisis that followed. In contrast to traditional monetarists, market monetarists do not believe monetary aggregates or commodity prices such as gold are the optimal guide to intervention. Market monetarists also reject the New Keynesian focus on interest rates as the primary instrument of monetary policy. Market monetarists prefer a nominal income target due to their twin beliefs that rational expectations are crucial to policy, and that markets react instantly to changes in their expectations about future policy, without the "long and variable lags" postulated by Milton Friedman.

A nominal income target is a monetary policy target. Such targets are adopted by central banks to manage national economic activity. Nominal aggregates are not adjusted for inflation. Nominal income aggregates that can serve as targets include nominal gross domestic product (NGDP) and nominal gross domestic income (GDI). Central banks use a variety of techniques to hit their targets, including conventional tools such as interest rate targeting or open market operations, unconventional tools such as quantitative easing or interest rates on excess reserves and expectations management to hit its target. The concept of NGDP targeting was formally proposed by neo-Keynesian economists James Meade in 1977 and James Tobin in 1980, although Austrian School economist Friedrich Hayek argued in favor of the stabilization of nominal income as a monetary policy norm as early as 1931 and as late as 1975.

In economics, divine coincidence refers to the property of New Keynesian models that there is no trade-off between the stabilization of inflation and the stabilization of the welfare-relevant output gap for central banks. This property is attributed to a feature of the model, namely the absence of real imperfections such as real wage rigidities. Conversely, if New Keynesian models are extended to account for these real imperfections, divine coincidence disappears and central banks again face a trade-off between inflation and output gap stabilization. The definition of divine coincidence is usually attributed to the seminal article by Olivier Blanchard and Jordi Galí in 2007.

The interest rate channel is a mechanism of monetary policy, whereby a policy-induced change in the short-term nominal interest rate by the central bank affects the price level, and subsequently output and employment.

A Calvo contract is the name given in macroeconomics to the pricing model that when a firm sets a nominal price there is a constant probability that a firm might be able to reset its price which is independent of the time since the price was last reset. The model was first put forward by Guillermo Calvo in his 1983 article "Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework". The original article was written in a continuous time mathematical framework, but nowadays is mostly used in its discrete time version. The Calvo model is the most common way to model nominal rigidity in new Keynesian DSGE macroeconomic models.

References

  1. Clement, Douglas, ed. (March 8, 2006). "Interview with John B. Taylor | Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis". www.minneapolisfed.org. Retrieved 2020-05-22.
  2. Judd, John P.; Trehan, Bharat (2020-04-30), "Has the Fed Gotten Tougher on Inflation?", Handbook of Monetary Policy, Routledge, pp. 635–639, doi:10.4324/9780429270949-48, ISBN   9780429270949, S2CID   154075608 , retrieved 2022-11-24
  3. 1 2 John B. Taylor, Discretion versus policy rules in practice (1993), Stanford University, y, Stanford, CA 94905
  4. 1 2 Mishkin, Frederic (February 2011). Monetary Policy Strategy: Lessons from the Crisis. National Bureau of Economic Research (Report). doi: 10.3386/w16755 .
  5. 1 2 Svensson, Lars E. O. (January 2003). What is Wrong with Taylor Rules? Using Judgment in Monetary Policy through Targeting Rules. National Bureau of Economic Research (Report). doi: 10.3386/w9421 .
  6. Taylor, John B. (January 2014). "Causes of the Financial Crisis and the Slow Recovery: A 10-Year Perspective | Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research (SIEPR)". siepr.stanford.edu. Hoover Institution Economics Working Paper. Retrieved 2022-11-24.
  7. 1 2 Asso, Pier Francesco; Kahn, George A.; Leeson, Robert (2010). "The Taylor Rule and the Practice of Central Banking". SSRN Electronic Journal. The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1553978. ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   153150134.
  8. 1 2 3 4 Hofmann, Boris (2012). Taylor Rules and Monetary Policy A Global 'Great Deviation'?. OCLC   1310400578.
  9. Lopez-Salido, David; Sanz-Maldonado, Gerardo; Schippits, Carly; Wei, Min (2020-06-19). "Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: The Role of Inflation Expectations". FEDS Notes.
  10. Orphanides, Athanasios (2008). "Taylor rules equation (7)". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics . Vol. 8 (2 ed.). pp. 2000–2004.[ dead link ]
  11. Davig, Troy; Leeper, Eric M. (2007). "Generalizing the Taylor Principle" (PDF). American Economic Review . 97 (3): 607–635. doi:10.1257/aer.97.3.607. JSTOR   30035014.
  12. Hetzel, Robert L. (1985). "The Rules versus Discretion Debate Over Monetary Policy in the 1920s" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
  13. Emiliano Brancaccio; Giuseppe Fontana, eds. (2011). The global economic crisis: new perspectives on the critique of economic theory and policy. Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge. ISBN   978-0-203-81672-1. OCLC   786002088.
  14. 1 2 Brancaccio, Emiliano; Fontana, Giuseppe (2013). "'Solvency rule' versus 'Taylor rule': an alternative interpretation of the relation between monetary policy and the economic crisis". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 37 (1): 17–33. doi:10.1093/cje/bes028. ISSN   0309-166X. JSTOR   23601922.
  15. Brancaccio, Emiliano; Califano, Andrea; Lopreite, Milena; Moneta, Alessio (2020-06-01). "Nonperforming loans and competing rules of monetary policy: A statistical identification approach". Structural Change and Economic Dynamics. 53: 127–136. doi:10.1016/j.strueco.2020.02.001. hdl: 11382/533350 . ISSN   0954-349X. S2CID   214323300.
  16. Gallmeyer, Michael; Hollifield, Burton; Zin, Stanley (April 2005). Taylor Rules, McCallum Rules and the Term Structure of Interest Rates. National Bureau of Economic Research (Report). doi: 10.3386/w11276 .
  17. 1 2 Clarida, Richard; Galí, Jordi; Gertler, Mark (2000). "Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Theory and Some Evidence". Quarterly Journal of Economics . 115 (1): 147–180. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.111.7984 . doi:10.1162/003355300554692. JSTOR   2586937. S2CID   5448436.
  18. Lowenstein, Roger (2008-01-20). "The Education of Ben Bernanke". The New York Times.
  19. Bernanke, Ben; Mihov, Ilian (1997). "What Does the Bundesbank Target?" (PDF). European Economic Review . 41 (6): 1025–1053. doi:10.1016/S0014-2921(96)00056-6. S2CID   154187980.
  20. Clarida, Richard; Gertler, Mark; Galí, Jordi (1998). "Monetary Policy Rules in Practice: Some International Evidence" (PDF). European Economic Review. 42 (6): 1033–1067. doi:10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00016-6. S2CID   158171496.
  21. Taylor, John B. (2008). "The Financial Crisis and the Policy Responses: An Empirical Analysis of What Went Wrong" (PDF).
  22. Taylor, John B. (2009). Getting Off Track: How Government Actions and Interventions Caused, Prolonged, and Worsened the Financial Crisis . Hoover Institution Press. ISBN   978-0-8179-4971-6.
  23. Carvalho, Carlos; Nechio, Fernanda (2013). "Do People Understand Monetary Policy?". Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2012-01. SSRN   1984321.
  24. Taylor, John B. (1993-12-01). "Discretion versus policy rules in practice" (PDF). Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. 39: 195–214. doi:10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-L. ISSN   0167-2231.
  25. Orphanides, A. (2003). "The Quest for Prosperity without Inflation". Journal of Monetary Economics . 50 (3): 633–663. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.196.7048 . doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(03)00028-X. S2CID   14305730.
  26. Bill Gross (July 30, 2015). "Gross: Low rates are the problem, not the solution". CNBC. Retrieved July 30, 2015.