Causes of income inequality in the United States

Last updated

Causes of income inequality in the United States describes the reasons for the unequal distribution of income in the US and the factors that cause it to change over time. This topic is subject to extensive ongoing research, media attention, and political interest.

Contents

U.S. inequality from 1913 to 2008. 2008 Top1percentUSA.svg
U.S. inequality from 1913 to 2008.

Income inequality in the United States grew significantly beginning in the early 1970s, [2] [3] [4] after several decades of stability. [5] [6] [7] The US consistently exhibits higher rates of income inequality than most developed nations, arguably due to the nation's relatively less regulated markets. [8] [9] [10]

According to the Congressional Budget Office, "the precise reasons for the [recent] rapid growth in income at the top are not well understood", but "in all likelihood," an "interaction of multiple factors" was involved. [11] Researchers have offered several potential rationales. [12] [13] Various rationales conflict or overlap. [14] They include:

Divergence of productivity and compensation

Illustrates the productivity gap (i.e., the annual growth rate in productivity minus annual growth rate in compensation) by industry from 1985 to 2015. Each dot is an industry; dots above the line have a productivity gap (i.e., productivity growth has exceeded compensation growth), those below the line do not. Productivity Gap - v1.png
Illustrates the productivity gap (i.e., the annual growth rate in productivity minus annual growth rate in compensation) by industry from 1985 to 2015. Each dot is an industry; dots above the line have a productivity gap (i.e., productivity growth has exceeded compensation growth), those below the line do not.

Overall

One view of economic equity is that employee compensation should rise with productivity (defined as real output per hour of labor worked). In other words, if the employee produces more, they should be paid accordingly. If pay lags behind productivity, income inequality grows, as labor's share of the output is falling, while capital's share (generally higher-income owners) is rising. According to a June 2017 report from the non-partisan Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), productivity rose in tandem with employee compensation (a measure which includes wages as well as benefits such as health insurance) from the 1940s through the 1970s. However, since then productivity has grown faster than compensation. BLS refers to this as the "productivity-compensation gap", an issue which has garnered much attention from academics and policymakers. [22] [23] BLS reported this gap occurs across most industries: "When examined at a detailed industry level, the average annual percent change in productivity outpaced compensation in 83 percent of 183 industries studied" measured from 1987 to 2015. [22] For example, in the information industry, productivity increased at an annual average rate of 5.0% over the 1987-2015 period, while compensation increased at about a 1.5% rate, resulting in a 3.5% productivity gap. In Manufacturing, the gap was 2.7%; in Retail Trade 2.6%; and in Transportation and Warehousing 1.3%. This analysis adjusted for inflation using the Consumer Price Index or CPI, a measure of inflation based on what is consumed, rather than what is produced. [22]

Analyzing the gap

BLS explained the gap between productivity and compensation can be divided into two components, the effect of which varies by industry: 1) Recalculating the gap using an industry-specific inflation adjustment ("industry deflator") rather than consumption (CPI); and 2) The change in labor's share of income, defined as how much of a business' revenue goes to workers as opposed to intermediate purchases (i.e., cost of goods) and capital (owners) in that industry. [22] The difference in deflators was the stronger effect among high productivity growth industries, while the change in labor's share of income was the stronger effect among most other industries. For example, the 3.5% productivity gap in the information industry was composed of a 2.1% difference in deflators and about a 1.4% due to change in labor share. The 2.7% gap in Manufacturing included 1.0% due to deflator and 1.7% due to change in labor share. [22]

Reasons for the gap

BLS explained the decline in labor share as likely driven by three factors that vary by industry:

Market factors

Globalization

Change in real income between 1988 and 2008 at various income percentiles of global income distribution. Global changes in real income by income percentile - v1.png
Change in real income between 1988 and 2008 at various income percentiles of global income distribution.
The bar chart compares pre-tax income shares of the top 1% in 13 developed countries for 1980 and 2000. The degree of change varied significantly, indicating country-specific policy factors also impact inequality. Income Shares of Top 1 Percent 1980 and 2000 - v1.png
The bar chart compares pre-tax income shares of the top 1% in 13 developed countries for 1980 and 2000. The degree of change varied significantly, indicating country-specific policy factors also impact inequality.

Globalization refers to the integration of economies in terms of trade, information, and jobs. Innovations in supply chain management enabled goods to be sourced in Asia and shipped to the United States less expensively than in the past. This integration of economies, particularly with the U.S. and Asia, had dramatic impacts on income inequality globally.

Economist Branko Milanovic analyzed global income inequality, comparing 1988 and 2008. His analysis indicated that the global top 1% and the middle classes of the emerging economies (e.g., China, India, Indonesia, Brazil and Egypt) were the main winners of globalization during that time. The real (inflation adjusted) income of the global top 1% increased approximately 60%, while the middle classes of the emerging economies (those around the 50th percentile of the global income distribution in 1988) rose 70–80%. For example, in 2000, 5 million Chinese households earned between $11,500 and $43,000 in 2016 dollars. By 2015, 225 million did. On the other hand, those in the middle class of the developed world (those in the 75th to 90th percentile in 1988, such as the American middle class) experienced little real income gains. The richest 1% contains 60 million persons globally, including 30 million Americans (i.e., the top 12% of Americans by income were in the global top 1% in 2008), the most out of any country. [24] [25] [26]

While economists who have studied globalization agree imports have had an effect, the timing of import growth does not match the growth of income inequality. By 1995 imports of manufactured goods from low-wage countries totalled less than 3% of US gross domestic product. [27]

It wasn't until 2006 that the US imported more manufactured goods from low-wage (developing) countries than from high-wage (advanced) economies. [28] Inequality increased during the 2000–2010 decade not because of stagnating wages for less-skilled workers, but because of accelerating incomes of the top 0.1%. [27] Author Timothy Noah estimates that "trade", increases in imports are responsible for just 10% of the "Great Divergence" in income distribution. [29]

Journalist James Surowiecki notes that in the last 50 years, companies and the sectors of the economy providing the most employment in the US – major retailers, restaurant chains, and supermarkets – are ones with lower profit margins and less pricing power than in the 1960s; while sectors with high profit margins and average salaries – like high technology – have relatively few employees. [30]

Some economists claim that it is WTO-led globalization and competition from developing countries, especially China, that has resulted in the recent decline in labor's share of income and increased unemployment in the U.S. [31] And the Economic Policy Institute and the Center for Economic and Policy Research argue that some trade agreements such as the Trans-Pacific Partnership could result in further job losses and declining wages. [32] [33]

One argument contrary to the globalization/technology hypothesis relates to variation across countries. Japan, Sweden and France did not experience significant increases in income inequality during the 1979–2010 period, although the U.S. did. The top 1% income group continued to receive less than 10% of the income share in these countries, while the U.S. share rose from 10% to over 20%. Economist Emmanuel Saez wrote in 2014: "Differences across countries rule out technical change/globalization as the sole explanation ... Policies play a key role in shaping inequality (tax and transfer policies, regulations, education)." [34]

Superstar hypothesis

Eric Posner and Glen Weyl point out that inequality can be predominantly explained by the superstar hypothesis. In their opinion Piketty fails to observe the accelerated turnover that is occurring in the Forbes 400; only 35 people from the original 1982 list remain today. Many have fallen off as a result of heavy spending, large-scale philanthropy, and bad investments. The current Forbes 400 is now primarily made up of newly wealthy business owners, not heirs and heiresses. [35] In parallel research, the University of Chicago's Steven Kaplan and Stanford University's Joshua Rauh note that 69% of those on the Forbes list are actually first generation wealth creators. That figure has risen dramatically since 1982 when it stood at 40%. [36]

Ed Dolan supports the globalization and superstar hypothesis but points out that the high earnings are based, to some extent, on moral hazard like "Bonus-based compensation schemes with inadequate clawback for losses" and the shift of losses to shareholders, unsecured creditors, or taxpayers. [37] Paul Krugman argues that for the US the surge in inequality to date is mainly due to supersalaries but capital has nonetheless been significant too. And when the current generation of the 1% turn over their wealth to their heirs these become rentiers, people who live off accumulated capital. Two decades from now America could turn into a rentier-dominated society even more unequal than Belle Époque Europe. [38]

One study extended the superstar hypothesis to corporations, with firms that are more dominant in their industry (in some cases due to oligopoly or monopoly) paying their workers far more than the average in the industry. Another study noted that "superstar firms" is another explanation for the decline in the overall share of income (GDP) going to workers/labor as opposed to owners/capital. [39]

Education

Median personal and household income according to different education levels. Education Median Income 2.png
Median personal and household income according to different education levels.

Income differences between the varying levels of educational attainment (usually measured by the highest degree of education an individual has completed) have increased. Expertise and skill certified through an academic degree translates into increased scarcity of an individual's occupational qualification which in turn leads to greater economic rewards. [42] As the United States has developed into a post-industrial society more and more employers require expertise that they did not a generation ago, while the manufacturing sector which employed many of those lacking a post-secondary education is decreasing in size. [43]

In the resulting economic job market the income discrepancy between the working class and the professional with the higher academic degrees, [44] who possess scarce amounts of certified expertise, may be growing.

Households in the upper quintiles are generally home to more, better educated and employed working income earners, than those in lower quintiles. [45] Among those in the upper quintile, 62% of householders were college graduates, 80% worked full-time and 76% of households had two or more income earners, compared to the national percentages of 27%, 58% and 42%, respectively. [44] [46] [47] Upper-most sphere US Census Bureau data indicated that occupational achievement and the possession of scarce skills correlates with higher income. [47]

Average earnings in 2002 for the population 18 years and over were higher at each progressively higher level of education ... This relationship holds true not only for the entire population but also across most subgroups. Within each specific educational level, earnings differed by sex and race. This variation may result from a variety of factors, such as occupation, working full- or part-time, age, or labor force experience. [44] [48]

The "college premium" refers to the increase in income to workers with four-year college degrees relative to those without. The college premium doubled from 1980 to 2005, as the demand for college-educated workers has exceeded the supply. Economists Goldin and Katz estimate that the increase in economic returns to education was responsible for about 60% of the increase in wage inequality between 1973 and 2005. The supply of available graduates did not keep up with business demand due primarily to increasingly expensive college educations. Annual tuition at public and private universities averaged 4% and 20% respectively of the annual median family income from the 1950s to 1970s; by 2005 these figures were 10% and 45% as colleges raised prices in response to demand. [49] Economist David Autor wrote in 2014 that approximately two-thirds of the rise in income inequality between 1980 and 2005 was accounted for by the increased premium associated with education in general and post-secondary education in particular. [50]

Two researchers have suggested that children in low income families are exposed to 636 words an hour, as opposed to 2,153 words in high income families during the first four formative years of a child's development. This, in turn, led to low achievement in later schooling due to the inability of the low income group to verbalize concepts. [51]

A psychologist has stated that society stigmatizes poverty. Conversely, poor people tend to believe that the wealthy have been lucky or have earned their money through illegal means. She believes that both attitudes need to be discarded if the nation is to make headway in addressing the issue of inequality. She suggests that college not be a litmus test of success; that valorizing of one profession as more important than another is a problem. [52]

Skill-biased technological change

U.S. real wages remain below their 1970's peak. U.S. Hourly Wages - Real or Adjusted for Inflation 1964-2014.png
U.S. real wages remain below their 1970's peak.

As of the mid- to late- decade of the 2000s, the most common explanation for income inequality in America was "skill-biased technological change" (SBTC) [54] – "a shift in the production technology that favors skilled over unskilled labor by increasing its relative productivity and, therefore, its relative demand". [55] For example, one scholarly colloquium on the subject that included many prominent labor economists estimated that technological change was responsible for over 40% of the increase in inequality. Other factors like international trade, decline in real minimum wage, decline in unionization and rising immigration, were each responsible for 10–15% of the increase. [56] [57]

Education has a notable influence on income distribution. [58] In 2005, roughly 55% of income earners with doctorate degrees – the most educated 1.4% – were among the top 15 percent earners. Among those with master's degrees – the most educated 10% – roughly half had incomes among the top 20 percent of earners. [40] Only among households in the top quintile were householders with college degrees in the majority. [46]

But while the higher education commonly translates into higher income, [58] and the highly educated are disproportionately represented in upper quintile households, differences in educational attainment fail to explain income discrepancies between the top 1 percent and the rest of the population. Large percentages of individuals lacking a college degree are present in all income demographics, including 33% of those with heading households with six figure incomes. [46] From 2000 to 2010, the 1.5% of Americans with an M.D., J.D., or M.B.A. and the 1.5% with a PhD saw median income gains of approximately 5%. Among those with a college or master's degree (about 25% of the American workforce) average wages dropped by about 7%, (though this was less than the decline in wages for those who had not completed college). [59] Post-2000 data has provided "little evidence" for SBTC's role in increasing inequality. The wage premium for college educated has risen little and there has been little shift in shares of employment to more highly skilled occupations. [60]

Approaching the issue from occupations that have been replaced or downgraded since the late 1970s, one scholar found that jobs that "require some thinking but not a lot" – or moderately skilled middle-class occupations such as cashiers, typists, welders, farmers, appliance repairmen – declined the furthest in wage rates and/or numbers. Employment requiring either more skill or less has been less affected. [61] However the timing of the great technological change of the era – internet use by business starting in the late 1990s – does not match that of the growth of income inequality (starting in the early 1970s but slackening somewhat in the 1990s). Nor does the introduction of technologies that increase the demand for more skilled workers seem to be generally associated with a divergence in household income among the population. Inventions of the 20th century such as AC electric power, the automobile, airplane, radio, television, the washing machine, Xerox machine, each had an economic impact similar to computers, microprocessors and internet, but did not coincide with greater inequality. [61]

Another explanation is that the combination of the introduction of technologies that increase the demand for skilled workers, and the failure of the American education system to provide a sufficient increase in those skilled workers has bid up those workers' salaries. An example of the slowdown in education growth in America (that began about the same time as the Great Divergence began) is the fact that the average person born in 1945 received two more years of schooling than his parents, while the average person born in 1975 received only half a year more of schooling. [29] Author Timothy Noah's "back-of-the-envelope" estimation based on "composite of my discussions with and reading of the various economists and political scientists" is that the "various failures" in America's education system are "responsible for 30%" of the post-1978 increase in inequality. [29]

Race and gender disparities

Median personal income by gender and race in 2005. Income inequity US.png
Median personal income by gender and race in 2005.

Income levels vary by gender and race with median income levels considerably below the national median for females compared to men with certain racial demographics. [62]

Despite considerable progress in pursuing gender and racial equality, some social scientists like Richard Schaeffer attribute these discrepancies in income partly to continued discrimination. [63]

Among women, part of the wage gap is due to employment choices and preferences. Women are more likely to consider factors other than salary when looking for employment. On average, women are less willing to travel or relocate, take more hours off and work fewer hours, and choose college majors that lead to lower paying jobs. Women are also more likely to work for governments or non-profits which pay less than the private sector. [64] [65] According to this perspective certain ethnic minorities and women receive fewer promotions and opportunities for occupation and economic advancement than others. In the case of women this concept is referred to as the glass ceiling keeping women from climbing the occupational ladder.

In terms of race, Asian Americans are far more likely to be in the highest earning 5 percent than the rest of Americans. [66] Studies have shown that African Americans are less likely to be hired than White Americans with the same qualifications. [67] The continued prevalence of traditional gender roles and ethnic stereotypes may partially account for current levels of discrimination. [63] In 2005, median income levels were highest among Asian and White males and lowest among females of all races, especially those identifying as African American or Hispanic. Despite closing gender and racial gaps, considerable discrepancies remain among racial and gender demographics, even at the same level of educational attainment. [68] The economic success of Asian Americans may come from how they devote much more time to education than their peers. Asian Americans have significantly higher college graduation rates than their peers and are much more likely to enter high status and high income occupations. [69]

Median weekly earnings of full-time wage and salary workers, by sex, race, and ethnicity, 2009. US gender pay gap, by sex, race-ethnicity-2009.png
Median weekly earnings of full-time wage and salary workers, by sex, race, and ethnicity, 2009.

Since 1953 the income gap between male and female workers has decreased considerably but remains relatively large. [71] Women currently earn significantly more Associate's, Bachelor's, and master's degrees than men and almost as many Doctorates. [72] Women are projected to have passed men in Doctorates earned in 2006–2007, and to earn nearly two thirds of Associate's, Bachelor's, and master's degrees by 2016. [73]

Though it is important to note that income inequality between sexes remained stark at all levels of educational attainment. [62] Between 1953 and 2005 median earnings as well as educational attainment increased, at a far greater pace for women than for men. Median income for female earners male earners increased 157.2% versus 36.2% for men, over four times as fast. Today the median male worker earns roughly 68.4% more than their female counterparts, compared to 176.3% in 1953. The median income of men in 2005 was 2% higher than in 1973 compared to a 74.6% increase for female earners. [71]

Racial differences remained stark as well, with the highest earning sex-gender demographic of workers aged 25 or older, Asian males (who were roughly tied with white males) earning slightly more than twice as much as the lowest-earning demographic, Hispanic females. [74] [75] As mentioned above, inequality between races and gender persisted at similar education levels. [75] [76] Racial differences were overall more pronounced among male than among female income earners. In 2009, Hispanics were more than twice as likely to be poor than non-Hispanic whites, research indicates. [77] Lower average English ability, low levels of educational attainment, part-time employment, the youthfulness of Hispanic household heads, and the 2007–09 recession are important factors that have pushed up the Hispanic poverty rate relative to non-Hispanic whites. During the early 1920s, median earnings decreased for both sexes, not increasing substantially until the late 1990s. Since 1974 the median income for workers of both sexes increased by 31.7% from $18,474 to $24,325, reaching its high-point in 2000. [78]

Incentives

Social connectedness to people of higher income levels is a strong predictor of upward income mobility. However, data shows substantial social segregation correlating with economic income groups. 20220801 Economic stratification - cross-class friendships - bar chart.svg
Social connectedness to people of higher income levels is a strong predictor of upward income mobility. However, data shows substantial social segregation correlating with economic income groups.
Percent of households with 2+ income earners, and full-time workers by income. Household Characteristics and Income.png
Percent of households with 2+ income earners, and full-time workers by income.

In the context of concern over income inequality, a number of economists, such as Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke, have talked about the importance of incentives: "... without the possibility of unequal outcomes tied to differences in effort and skill, the economic incentive for productive behavior would be eliminated, and our market-based economy ... would function far less effectively." [42] [80]

Since abundant supply decreases market value, the possession of scarce skills considerably increases income. [44] Among the American lower class, the most common source of income was not occupation, but government welfare. [81]

Stock buybacks

Writing in the Harvard Business Review in September 2014, William Lazonick blamed record corporate stock buybacks for reduced investment in the economy and a corresponding impact on prosperity and income inequality. Between 2003 and 2012, the 449 companies in the S&P 500 used 54% of their earnings ($2.4 trillion) to buy back their own stock. An additional 37% was paid to stockholders as dividends. Together, these were 91% of profits. This left little for investment in productive capabilities or higher income for employees, shifting more income to capital rather than labor. He blamed executive compensation arrangements, which are heavily based on stock options, stock awards and bonuses for meeting earnings per share (EPS) targets (EPS increases as the number of outstanding shares decreases). Restrictions on buybacks were greatly eased in the early 1980s. He advocates changing these incentives to limit buybacks. [82]

U.S. companies are projected to increase buybacks to $701 billion in 2015 according to Goldman Sachs, an 18% increase over 2014. For scale, annual non-residential fixed investment (a proxy for business investment and a major GDP component) was estimated to be about $2.1 trillion for 2014. [83] [84]

Journalist Timothy Noah wrote in 2012 that: "My own preferred hypothesis is that stockholders appropriated what once belonged to middle-class wage earners." Since the vast majority of stocks are owned by higher income households, this contributes to income inequality. [49] Journalist Harold Meyerson wrote in 2014 that: "The purpose of the modern U.S. corporation is to reward large investors and top executives with income that once was spent on expansion, research, training and employees." [85]

Tax and transfer policies

Background

Distribution of US federal taxes from 1979 to 2013, based on CBO Estimates. Average US Federal Tax Rates 1979 to 2013.png
Distribution of US federal taxes from 1979 to 2013, based on CBO Estimates.

U.S. income inequality is comparable to other developed nations pre-tax, but is among the worst after-tax and transfers. This indicates the U.S. tax policies redistribute income from higher income to lower income households relatively less than other developed countries. [18] Journalist Timothy Noah summarized the results of several studies his 2012 book The Great Divergence:

Income taxes

Total effective tax rates (includes all taxes: federal+state income tax, sales tax, property tax, etc.) for the richest Americans declined by 2018 to a level beneath that of the bottom 50% of earners, contributing to net income inequality. Analysis by economists Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman. 1960- Tax rates of richest versus low income people - US.svg
Total effective tax rates (includes all taxes: federal+state income tax, sales tax, property tax, etc.) for the richest Americans declined by 2018 to a level beneath that of the bottom 50% of earners, contributing to net income inequality. Analysis by economists Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman.
Share of income tax paid by level of income. The top 2.7% of taxpayers (those with income over $250,000) paid 51.6% of the federal income taxes in 2014. US Share of Income Taxes Paid by Income Level v1.png
Share of income tax paid by level of income. The top 2.7% of taxpayers (those with income over $250,000) paid 51.6% of the federal income taxes in 2014.

A key factor in income inequality/equality is the effective rate at which income is taxed coupled with the progressivity of the tax system. A progressive tax is a tax in which the effective tax rate increases as the taxable base amount increases. [89] [90] [91] [92] [93] Overall income tax rates in the U.S. are below the OECD average, and until 2005 have been declining. [94]

How much tax policy change over the last thirty years has contributed to income inequality is disputed. In their comprehensive 2011 study of income inequality (Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007), [95] the CBO found that,

The top fifth of the population saw a 10-percentage-point increase in their share of after-tax income. Most of that growth went to the top 1 percent of the population. All other groups saw their shares decline by 2 to 3 percentage points. In 2007, federal taxes and transfers reduced the dispersion of income by 20 percent, but that equalizing effect was larger in 1979. The share of transfer payments to the lowest-income households declined. The overall average federal tax rate fell.

However, a more recent CBO analysis indicates that with changes to 2013 tax law (e.g., the expiration of the 2001-2003 Bush tax cuts for top earners and the increased payroll taxes passed as part of the Affordable Care Act), the effective federal tax rates for the highest earning household will increase to levels not seen since 1979. [86]

According to journalist Timothy Noah, "you can't really demonstrate that U.S. tax policy had a large impact on the three-decade income inequality trend one way or the other. The inequality trend for pre-tax income during this period was much more dramatic." [96] Noah estimates tax changes account for 5% of the Great Divergence. [29]

But many – such as economist Paul Krugman – emphasize the effect of changes in taxation – such as the 2001 and 2003 Bush administration tax cuts which cut taxes far more for high-income households than those below – on increased income inequality. [97]

Part of the growth of income inequality under Republican administrations (described by Larry Bartels) has been attributed to tax policy. A study by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez found that "large reductions in tax progressivity since the 1960s took place primarily during two periods: the Reagan presidency in the 1980s and the Bush administration in the early 2000s." [98]

During Republican President Ronald Reagan's tenure in office the top marginal income tax rate was reduced from over 70 to 28 percent, high top marginal rates like 70% being the sort in place during much of the period of great income equality following the "Great Compression". [96] The lowest marginal rate for the bottom fell from 14 to 11 percent. [99] However the effective rate on top earners before Reagan's tax cut was much lower because of loopholes and charitable contributions. [100] [101]

Robert Bellafiore and Madison Mauro, writing for the Tax Foundation, calculated that effective tax rates for the richest Americans has declined since 1986. But the share of income taxes paid by the richest Americans has increased, due to tax expenditures increasing the number of low-income Americans with negative tax rates. [102]

Taxes on capital

Selected economic variables related to wealth and income equality, comparing 1979, 2007, and 2015. U.S. economic variables related to the distribution of wealth and income.png
Selected economic variables related to wealth and income equality, comparing 1979, 2007, and 2015.

Taxes on income derived from capital (e.g., financial assets, property and businesses) primarily affect higher income groups, who own the vast majority of capital. For example, in 2010 approximately 81% of stocks were owned by the top 10% income group and 69% by the top 5%. Only about one-third of American households have stock holdings more than $7,000. Therefore, since higher-income taxpayers have a much higher share of their income represented by capital gains, lowering taxes on capital income and gains increases after-tax income inequality. [49]

Capital gains taxes were reduced around the time income inequality began to rise again around 1980 and several times thereafter. During 1978 under President Jimmy Carter, the top capital gains tax rate was reduced from 49% to 28%. President Ronald Reagan's 1981 cut in the top rate on unearned income reduced the maximum capital gains rate to only 20% – its lowest level since the Hoover administration, as part of an overall economic growth strategy. The capital gains tax rate was also reduced by President Bill Clinton in 1997, from 28% to 20%. President George W. Bush reduced the tax rate on capital gains and qualifying dividends from 20% to 15%, less than half the 35% top rate on ordinary income. [103]

CBO reported in August 1990 that: "Of the 8 studies reviewed, five, including the two CBO studies, found that cutting taxes on capital gains is not likely to increase savings, investment, or GNP much if at all." Some of the studies indicated the loss in revenue from lowering the tax rate may be offset by higher economic growth, others did not. [104]

Journalist Timothy Noah wrote in 2012 that: "Every one of these changes elevated the financial interests of business owners and stockholders above the well-being, financial or otherwise, or ordinary citizens." [49] So overall, while cutting capital gains taxes adversely affects income inequality, its economic benefits are debatable.

Other tax policies

Rising inequality has also been attributed to President Bush's veto of tax harmonization, as this would have prohibited offshore tax havens. [105]

Debate over effects of tax policies

Proposed tax plan payment rates by income group as a percentage of income, including mandatory health insurance, of four 2020 United States presidential election candidates Tax proposals of 2020 US presidential candidates.jpg
Proposed tax plan payment rates by income group as a percentage of income, including mandatory health insurance, of four 2020 United States presidential election candidates

One study [106] found reductions of total effective tax rates were most significant for individuals with highest incomes. (see "Federal Tax Rate by Income Group" chart) For those with incomes in the top 0.01 percent, overall rates of Federal tax fell from 74.6% in 1970, to 34.7% in 2004 (the reversal of the trend in 2000 with a rise to 40.8% came after the 1993 Clinton deficit reduction tax bill), the next 0.09 percent falling from 59.1% to 34.1%, before leveling off with a relatively modest drop of 41.4 to 33.0% for the 99.5–99.9 percent group. Although the tax rate for low-income earners fell as well (though not as much), these tax reductions compare with virtually no change – 23.3% tax rate in 1970, 23.4% in 2004 – for the US population overall. [106]

We haven't achieved the minimalist state that libertarians advocate. What we've achieved is a state too constrained to provide the public goods—investments in infrastructure, technology, and education—that would make for a vibrant economy and too weak to engage in the redistribution that is needed to create a fair society. But we have a state that is still large enough and distorted enough that it can provide a bounty of gifts to the wealthy.

Joseph Stiglitz [107]

The study found the decline in progressivity since 1960 was due to the shift from allocation of corporate income taxes among labor and capital to the effects of the individual income tax. [106] [108] Paul Krugman also supports this claim saying, "The overall tax rate on these high income families fell from 36.5% in 1980 to 26.7% in 1989." [109]

From the White House's own analysis, the federal tax burden for those making greater than $250,000 fell considerably during the late 1980s, 1990s and 2000s, from an effective tax of 35% in 1980, down to under 30% from the late 1980s to 2011. [110]

Many studies argue that tax changes of S corporations confound the statistics prior to 1990. However, even after these changes inflation-adjusted average after-tax income grew by 25% between 1996 and 2006 (the last year for which individual income tax data is publicly available). This average increase, however, obscures a great deal of variation. The poorest 20% of tax filers experienced a 6% reduction in income while the top 0.1 percent of tax filers saw their income almost double. Tax filers in the middle of the income distribution experienced about a 10% increase in income. Also during this period, the proportion of income from capital increased for the top 0.1 percent from 64% to 70%. [111]

Transfer payments

Transfer payments refer to payments to persons such as social security, unemployment compensation, or welfare. CBO reported in November 2014 that: "Government transfers reduce income inequality because the transfers received by lower-income households are larger relative to their market income than are the transfers received by higher-income households. Federal taxes also reduce income inequality, because the taxes paid by higher-income households are larger relative to their before-tax income than are the taxes paid by lower-income households. The equalizing effects of government transfers were significantly larger than the equalizing effects of federal taxes from 1979 to 2011. [112]

CBO also reported that less progressive tax and transfer policies have contributed to greater after-tax income inequality: "As a result of the diminishing effect of transfers and federal taxes, the Gini index for income after transfers and federal taxes grew by more than the index for market income. Between 1979 and 2007, the Gini index for market income increased by 23 percent, the index for market income after transfers increased by 29 percent, and the index for income measured after transfers and federal taxes increased by 33 percent." [112]

Tax expenditures

CBO charts describing amount and distribution of top 10 tax expenditures (i.e., exemptions, deductions, and preferential rates) CBO tax expenditures panel v1.png
CBO charts describing amount and distribution of top 10 tax expenditures (i.e., exemptions, deductions, and preferential rates)

Tax expenditures (i.e., exclusions, deductions, preferential tax rates, and tax credits) cause revenues to be much lower than they would otherwise be for any given tax rate structure. The benefits from tax expenditures, such as income exclusions for healthcare insurance premiums paid for by employers and tax deductions for mortgage interest, are distributed unevenly across the income spectrum. They are often what the Congress offers to special interests in exchange for their support. According to a report from the CBO that analyzed the 2013 data:

Understanding how each tax expenditure is distributed across the income spectrum can inform policy choices. [113] [114]

Other causes

Shifts in political power

Paul Krugman wrote in 2015 that: "Economists struggling to make sense of economic polarization are, increasingly, talking not about technology but about power." This market power hypothesis basically asserts that market power has concentrated in monopolies and oligopolies that enable unusual amounts of income ("rents") to be transferred from the many consumers to relatively few owners. This hypothesis is consistent with higher corporate profits without a commensurate rise in investment, as firms facing less competition choose to pass a greater share of their profits to shareholders (such as through share buybacks and dividends) rather than re-invest in the business to ward off competitors. [115]

One cause of this concentration of market power was the rightward shift in American politics toward more conservative policies since 1980, as politics plays a big role in how market power can be exercised. Policies that removed barriers to monopoly and oligopoly included anti-union laws, reduced anti-trust activity, deregulation (or failure to regulate) non-depository banking, contract laws that favored creditors over debtors, etc. Further, rising wealth concentration can be used to purchase political influence, creating a feedback loop. [115]

Decline of unions

Income inequality and union participation have had a distinctly inverse relationship, with the disparity increasing since the 1980s. 1907- Income inequality and union participation.svg
Income inequality and union participation have had a distinctly inverse relationship, with the disparity increasing since the 1980s.

The era of inequality growth has coincided with a dramatic decline in labor union membership from 20% of the labor force in 1983 to about 12% in 2007. [117] Classical and neoclassical economists have traditionally thought that since the chief purpose of a union is to maximize the income of its members, a strong but not all-encompassing union movement would lead to increased income inequality. However, given the increase in income inequality of the past few decades, either the sign of the effect must be reversed, or the magnitude of the effect must be small and a much larger opposing force has overridden it. [118] [119]

The decline in unionization in recent decades has fed the rise in incomes at the top.

—2015 IMF report [120]

However, more recently, research has shown that unions' ability to reduce income disparities among members outweighed other factors and its net effect has been to reduce national income inequality. [119] [121] The decline of unions has hurt this leveling effect among men, and one economist (Berkeley economist David Card) estimating about 15–20% of the "Great Divergence" among that gender is the result of declining unionization. [119] [122]

According to scholars, "As organized labor's political power dissipates, economic interests in the labor market are dispersed and policy makers have fewer incentives to strengthen unions or otherwise equalize economic rewards." [123] [124] [125] [126] [127] [128] Unions were a balancing force, helping ensure wages kept up with productivity and that neither executives nor shareholders were unduly rewarded. Further, societal norms placed constraints on executive pay. This changed as union power declined (the share of unionized workers fell significantly during the Great Divergence, from over 30% to around 12%) and CEO pay skyrocketed (rising from around 40 times the average workers pay in the 1970s to over 350 times in the early 2000s). [20] [21] A 2015 report by the International Monetary Fund also attributes the decline of labor's share of GDP to deunionization, noting the trend "necessarily increases the income share of corporate managers' pay and shareholder returns ... Moreover, weaker unions can reduce workers' influence on corporate decisions that benefit top earners, such as the size and structure of top executive compensation." [129]

Still other researchers think it is the labor movement's loss of national political power to promote equalizing "government intervention and changes in private sector behavior" has had the greatest impact on inequality in the US. [119] [130] Sociologist Jake Rosenfeld of the University of Washington argues that labor unions were the primary institution fighting inequality in the United States and helped grow a multiethnic middle class, and their decline has resulted in diminishing prospects for U.S. workers and their families. [131] Timothy Noah estimates the "decline" of labor union power "responsible for 20%" of the Great Divergence. [29] While the decline of union power in the US has been a factor in declining middle class incomes, [132] they have retained their clout in Western Europe. [133] In Denmark, influential trade unions such as Fagligt Fælles Forbund (3F) ensure that fast-food workers earn a living wage, the equivalent of $20 an hour, which is more than double the hourly rate for their counterparts in the United States. [134]

Critics of technological change as an explanation for the "Great Divergence" of income levels in America [135] point to public policy and party politics, or "stuff the government did, or didn't do". [96] They argue these have led to a trend of declining labor union membership rates and resulting diminishing political clout, decreased expenditure on social services, and less government redistribution. Moreover, the United States is the only advanced economy without a labor-based political party. [136]

As of 2011, several state legislatures have launched initiatives aimed at lowering wages, labor standards, and workplace protections for both union and non-union workers. [137]

The economist Joseph Stiglitz argues that "Strong unions have helped to reduce inequality, whereas weaker unions have made it easier for CEOs, sometimes working with market forces that they have helped shape, to increase it." The long fall in unionization in the U.S. since WWII has seen a corresponding rise in the inequality of wealth and income. [138] A study by Kristal and Cohen reported that rising wage inequality was driven more by declining unions and the fall in the real value of the minimum wage, with twice as much impact as technology. [139]

Political parties and presidents

Liberal political scientist Larry Bartels has found a strong correlation between the party of the president and income inequality in America since 1948. (see below) [140] [141] Examining average annual pre-tax income growth from 1948 to 2005 (which encompassed most of the egalitarian Great Compression and the entire inegalitarian Great Divergence) [142] Bartels shows that under Democratic presidents (from Harry Truman forward), the greatest income gains have been at the bottom of the income scale and tapered off as income rose. Under Republican presidents, in contrast, gains were much less but what growth there was concentrated towards the top, tapering off as you went down the income scale. [143] [144]

Summarizing Bartels's findings, journalist Timothy Noah referred to the administrations of Democratic presidents as "Democrat-world", and GOP administrations as "Republican-world":

In Democrat-world, pre-tax income increased 2.64% annually for the poor and lower-middle-class and 2.12% annually for the upper-middle-class and rich. There was no Great Divergence. Instead, the Great Compression – the egalitarian income trend that prevailed through the 1940s, 1950s, and 1960s – continued to the present, albeit with incomes converging less rapidly than before. In Republican-world, meanwhile, pre-tax income increased 0.43 percent annually for the poor and lower-middle-class and 1.90 percent for the upper-middle-class and rich. Not only did the Great Divergence occur; it was more greatly divergent. Also of note: In Democrat-world pre-tax income increased faster than in the real world not just for the 20th percentile but also for the 40th, 60th, and 80th. We were all richer and more equal! But in Republican-world, pre-tax income increased slower than in the real world not just for the 20th percentile but also for the 40th, 60th, and 80th. We were all poorer and less equal! Democrats also produced marginally faster income growth than Republicans at the 95th percentile, but the difference wasn't statistically significant. [96]

The pattern of distribution of growth appears to be the result of a whole host of policies,

including not only the distribution of taxes and benefits but also the government's stance toward unions, whether the minimum wage rises, the extent to which the government frets about inflation versus too-high interest rates, etc., etc. [143]

Noah admits the evidence of this correlation is "circumstantial rather than direct", but so is "the evidence that smoking is a leading cause of lung cancer." [96]

The economic grievance thesis argues that economic factors, such as deindustrialisation, economic liberalisation, and deregulation, are causing the formation of a 'left-behind' precariat with low job security, high inequality, and wage stagnation, who then support populism. [145] [146] Some theories only focus on the effect of economic crises, [147] or inequality. [148] Another objection for economic reasons is due to the globalization that is taking place in the world today. In addition to criticism of the widening inequality caused by the elite, the widening inequality among the general public caused by the influx of immigrants and other factors due to globalization is also a target of populist criticism.

The evidence of increasing economic disparity and volatility of family incomes is clear, particularly in the United States, as shown by the work of Thomas Piketty and others. [149] [150] [151] Commentators such as Martin Wolf emphasize the importance of economics. [152] They warn that such trends increase resentment and make people susceptible to populist rhetoric. Evidence for this is mixed. At the macro level, political scientists report that xenophobia, anti-immigrant ideas, and resentment towards out-groups tend to be higher during difficult economic times. [149] [153] Economic crises have been associated with gains by far-right political parties. [154] [155] However, there is little evidence at the micro- or individual level to link individual economic grievances and populist support. [149] [145] Populist politicians tend to put pressure on central bank independence. [156]

In his 2017 book The Great Leveler, historian Walter Scheidel point out that, starting in the 1970s, both parties shifted towards promoting free market capitalism, with Republicans moving further to the political right than Democrats to the political left. He notes that Democrats have been instrumental in the financial deregulation of the 1990s and have largely neglected social welfare issues while increasingly focusing on issues pertaining to identity politics. [157] The Clinton Administration in particular continued promoting free market, or neoliberal, reforms which began under the Reagan Administration. [158] [159]

Non-party political action

Ratio of average compensation of CEOs and production workers, 1965-2009. Source: Economic Policy Institute. 2011. Based on data from Wall Street Journal/Mercer, Hay Group 2010. CEO pay v. average slub.png
Ratio of average compensation of CEOs and production workers, 1965–2009. Source: Economic Policy Institute. 2011. Based on data from Wall Street Journal/Mercer, Hay Group 2010.

According to political scientists Jacob Hacker and Paul Pierson writing in the book Winner-Take-All Politics, the important policy shifts were brought on not by the Republican Party but by the development of a modern, efficient political system, especially lobbying, by top earners – and particularly corporate executives and the financial services industry. [161] The end of the 1970s saw a transformation of American politics away from a focus on the middle class, with new, much more effective, aggressive and well-financed lobbyists and pressure groups acting on behalf of upper income groups. Executives successfully eliminated any countervailing power or oversight of corporate managers (from private litigation, boards of directors and shareholders, the Securities and Exchange Commission or labor unions). [162]

The financial industry's success came from successfully pushing for deregulation of financial markets, allowing much more lucrative but much more risky investments from which it privatized the gains while socializing the losses with government bailouts. [163] (the two groups formed about 60% of the top 0.1 percent of earners.) All top earners were helped by deep cuts in estate and capital gains taxes, and tax rates on high levels of income.

Arguing against the proposition that the explosion in pay for corporate executives – which grew from 35X average worker pay in 1978 to over 250X average pay before the 2007 recession [164] – is driven by an increased demand for scarce talent and set according to performance, Krugman points out that multiple factors outside of executives' control govern corporate profitability, particularly in short term when the head of a company like Enron may look like a great success. Further, corporate boards follow other companies in setting pay even if the directors themselves disagree with lavish pay "partly to attract executives whom they consider adequate, partly because the financial market will be suspicious of a company whose CEO isn't lavishly paid." Finally "corporate boards, largely selected by the CEO, hire compensation experts, almost always chosen by the CEO" who naturally want to please their employers. [165]

Lucian Arye Bebchuk, Jesse M. Fried, the authors of Pay Without Performance, critique of executive pay, argue that executive capture of corporate governance is so complete that only public relations, i.e. public `outrage`, constrains their pay. [166] This in turn has been reduced as traditional critics of excessive pay – such as politicians (where need for campaign contributions from the richest outweighs populist indignation), media (lauding business genius), unions (crushed) – are now silent. [167]

In addition to politics, Krugman postulated change in norms of corporate culture have played a factor. In the 1950s and 60s, corporate executives had (or could develop) the ability to pay themselves very high compensation through control of corporate boards of directors, they restrained themselves. But by the end of the 1990s, the average real annual compensation of the top 100 C.E.O.'s skyrocketed from $1.3 million – 39 times the pay of an average worker – to $37.5 million, more than 1,000 times the pay of ordinary workers from 1982 to 2002. [15] Journalist George Packer also sees the dramatic increase in inequality in America as a product of the change in attitude of the American elite, which (in his view) has been transitioning itself from pillars of society to a special interest group. [168] Author Timothy Noah estimates that what he calls "Wall Street and corporate boards' pampering" of the highest earning 0.1% is "responsible for 30%" of the post-1978 increase in inequality. [29]

Immigration

Foreign-born in US labor force 1900-2015 Chart of foreign born in the US labor force 1900 to 2007.png
Foreign-born in US labor force 1900-2015

The Immigration and Nationality Act of 1965 increased immigration to America, especially of non-Europeans. [169] From 1970 to 2007, the foreign-born proportion of America's population grew from 5% to 11%, most of whom had lower education levels and incomes than native-born Americans. But the contribution of this increase in supply of low-skill labor seem to have been relatively modest. One estimate stated that immigration reduced the average annual income of native-born "high-school dropouts" ("who roughly correspond to the poorest tenth of the workforce") by 7.4% from 1980 to 2000. The decline in income of better educated workers was much less. [169] Author Timothy Noah estimates that "immigration" is responsible for just 5% of the "Great Divergence" in income distribution, [29] as does economist David Card. [170]

While immigration was found to have slightly depressed the wages of the least skilled and least educated American workers, it doesn't explain rising inequality among high school and college graduates. [171] Scholars such as political scientists Jacob S. Hacker, Paul Pierson, Larry Bartels and Nathan Kelly, and economist Timothy Smeeding question the explanation of educational attainment and workplace skills point out that other countries with similar education levels and economies have not gone the way of the US, and that the concentration of income in the US hasn't followed a pattern of "the 29% of Americans with college degrees pulling away" from those who have less education. [8] [140] [172] [173] [174] [175]

Wage theft

A September 2014 report by the Economic Policy Institute claims wage theft is also responsible for exacerbating income inequality: "Survey evidence suggests that wage theft is widespread and costs workers billions of dollars a year, a transfer from low-income employees to business owners that worsens income inequality, hurts workers and their families, and damages the sense of fairness and justice that a democracy needs to survive." [176]

Corporatism

Labor's share of GDP has declined 1970 to 2013, measured based on total compensation as well as salaries & wages. This implies capital's share is increasing. U.S. Compensation as Percent of GDP - v1.png
Labor's share of GDP has declined 1970 to 2013, measured based on total compensation as well as salaries & wages. This implies capital's share is increasing.

Edmund Phelps, published an analysis in 2010 theorizing that the cause of income inequality is not free market capitalism, but instead is the result of the rise of corporatism. [177] Corporatism, in his view, is the antithesis of free market capitalism. It is characterized by semi-monopolistic organizations and banks, big employer confederations, often acting with complicit state institutions in ways that discourage (or block) the natural workings of a free economy. The primary effects of corporatism are the consolidation of economic power and wealth with end results being the attrition of entrepreneurial and free market dynamism.

His follow-up book, Mass Flourishing, further defines corporatism by the following attributes: power-sharing between government and large corporations (exemplified in the U.S. by widening government power in areas such as financial services, healthcare, and energy through regulation), an expansion of corporate lobbying and campaign support in exchange for government reciprocity, escalation in the growth and influence of financial and banking sectors, increased consolidation of the corporate landscape through merger and acquisition (with ensuing increases in corporate executive compensation), increased potential for corporate/government corruption and malfeasance, and a lack of entrepreneurial and small business development leading to lethargic and stagnant economic conditions. [178] [179]

Today, in the United States, virtually all of these economic conditions are being borne out. With regard to income inequality, the 2014 income analysis of University of California, Berkeley economist Emmanuel Saez confirms that relative growth of income and wealth is not occurring among small and mid-sized entrepreneurs and business owners (who generally populate the lower half of top one per-centers in income), [180] but instead only among the top .1 percent of income distribution ... whom Paul Krugman describes as "super-elites - corporate bigwigs and financial wheeler-dealers." [181] [182] ... who earn $2,000,000 or more every year. [183] [184]

For example, measured relative to GDP, total compensation and its component wages and salaries have been declining since 1970. This indicates a shift in income from labor (persons who derive income from hourly wages and salaries) to capital (persons who derive income via ownership of businesses, land and assets). [185] Wages and salaries have fallen from approximately 51% GDP in 1970 to 43% GDP in 2013. Total compensation has fallen from approximately 58% GDP in 1970 to 53% GDP in 2013. [186] To put this in perspective, five percent of U.S. GDP was approximately $850 billion in 2013. This represents an additional $7,000 in wages and salaries for each of the 120 million U.S. households. Larry Summers estimated in 2007 that the lower 80% of families were receiving $664 billion less income than they would be with a 1979 income distribution (a period of much greater equality), or approximately $7,000 per family. [187]

Not receiving this income may have led many families to increase their debt burden, a significant factor in the 2007–2009 subprime mortgage crisis, as highly leveraged homeowners suffered a much larger reduction in their net worth during the crisis. Further, since lower income families tend to spend relatively more of their income than higher income families, shifting more of the income to wealthier families may slow economic growth. [188]

In another example, The Economist propounds that a swelling corporate financial and banking sector has caused Gini Coefficients to rise in the U.S. since 1980: "Financial services' share of GDP in America doubled to 8% between 1980 and 2000; over the same period their profits rose from about 10% to 35% of total corporate profits, before collapsing in 2007–09. Bankers are being paid more, too. In America the compensation of workers in financial services was similar to average compensation until 1980. Now it is twice that average." [189] The summary argument, considering these findings, is that if corporatism is the consolidation and sharing of economic and political power between large corporations and the state ... then a corresponding concentration of income and wealth (with resulting income inequality) is an expected by-product of such a consolidation.

Neoliberalism

Some economists, sociologists and anthropologists argue that neoliberalism, or the resurgence of 19th century theories relating to laissez-faire economic liberalism in the late 1970s, has been the significant driver of inequality. [199] More broadly, according to The Handbook of Neoliberalism, the term has "become a means of identifying a seemingly ubiquitous set of market-oriented policies as being largely responsible for a wide range of social, political, ecological and economic problems." [200] Vicenç Navarro points to policies pertaining to the deregulation of labor markets, privatization of public institutions, union busting and reduction of public social expenditures as contributors to this widening disparity. [197] The privatization of public functions, for example, grows income inequality by depressing wages and eliminating benefits for middle class workers while increasing income for those at the top. [201] The deregulation of the labor market undermined unions by allowing the real value of the minimum wage to plummet, resulting in employment insecurity and widening wage and income inequality. [202] David M. Kotz, professor of economics at the University of Massachusetts Amherst, contends that neoliberalism "is based on the thorough domination of labor by capital." [203] As such, the advent of the neoliberal era has seen a sharp increase in income inequality through shifting the distribution of income from labor to capital, leading to the decline of unionization, stagnant wages for workers (even as productivity has increased) and the rise of CEO supersalaries. [203] [204] According to Emmanuel Saez:

The labor market has been creating much more inequality over the last thirty years, with the very top earners capturing a large fraction of macroeconomic productivity gains. A number of factors may help explain this increase in inequality, not only underlying technological changes but also the retreat of institutions developed during the New Deal and World War II - such as progressive tax policies, powerful unions, corporate provision of health and retirement benefits, and changing social norms regarding pay inequality. [205]

Pennsylvania State University political science professor Pamela Blackmon attributes the trends of growing poverty and income inequality to the convergence of several neoliberal policies during Ronald Reagan's presidency, including the decreased funding of education, decreases in the top marginal tax rates, and shifts in transfer programs for those in poverty. [206] Journalist Mark Bittman echoes this sentiment in a 2014 piece for The New York Times :

The progress of the last 40 years has been mostly cultural, culminating, the last couple of years, in the broad legalization of same-sex marriage. But by many other measures, especially economic, things have gotten worse, thanks to the establishment of neo-liberal principles — anti-unionism, deregulation, market fundamentalism and intensified, unconscionable greed — that began with Richard Nixon and picked up steam under Ronald Reagan. Too many are suffering now because too few were fighting then. [207]

Fred L. Block and Margaret Somers, in expanding on Karl Polanyi's critique of laissez-faire theories in The Great Transformation , argue that Polanyi's analysis helps to explain why the revival of such ideas has contributed to the "persistent unemployment, widening inequality, and the severe financial crises that have stressed Western economies over the past forty years." [208] John Schmitt and Ben Zipperer of the Center for Economic and Policy Research also point to economic liberalism as one of the causes of income inequality. They note that European nations, in particular the social democracies of Northern Europe with extensive and well funded welfare states, have lower levels of income inequality and social exclusion than the United States. [209]

Jonathan Hopkin writes the United States is an outlier regarding economic inequality which hit "unprecedented levels for the rich democracies" as it took the lead in implementing the neoliberal agenda in the 1980s, making it "the most extreme case of the subjection of society to the brute force of the market." He adds that even with average incomes "very high by global standards," US citizens "face greater material hardship than their counterparts in much poorer countries." These developments, he concludes, have resulted in the social and political upheavals affecting the United States. [210]

Dean Baker argued in 2006 that the driving force behind rising inequality in the United States has been a series of deliberate neoliberal policy choices, including anti-inflationary bias, anti-unionism and profiteering in the healthcare industry. [211] The economists David Howell and Mamadou Diallo contend that neoliberal policies have contributed to a United States economy in which 30% of workers earn low wages (less than two-thirds the median wage for full-time workers) and 35% of the labor force is underemployed while only 40% of the working-age population in the country is adequately employed. [212]

See also

Related Research Articles

A minimum wage is the lowest remuneration that employers can legally pay their employees—the price floor below which employees may not sell their labor. Most countries had introduced minimum wage legislation by the end of the 20th century. Because minimum wages increase the cost of labor, companies often try to avoid minimum wage laws by using gig workers, by moving labor to locations with lower or nonexistent minimum wages, or by automating job functions. Minimum wage policies can vary significantly between countries or even within a country, with different regions, sectors, or age groups having their own minimum wage rates. These variations are often influenced by factors such as the cost of living, regional economic conditions, and industry-specific factors.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Reaganomics</span> Economic policies of Ronald Reagan

Reaganomics, or Reaganism, were the neoliberal economic policies promoted by U.S. President Ronald Reagan during the 1980s. These policies are characterized as supply-side economics, trickle-down economics, or "voodoo economics" by opponents, including some Republicans, while Reagan and his advocates preferred to call it free-market economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economy of the United States</span>

The United States is a highly developed mixed economy. It is the world's largest economy by nominal GDP; it is also the second largest by purchasing power parity (PPP), behind China. It has the world's sixth highest per capita GDP (nominal) and the eighth highest per capita GDP (PPP) as of 2024. The U.S. accounted for 26% of the global economy in 2023 in nominal terms, and about 15.5% in PPP terms. The U.S. dollar is the currency of record most used in international transactions and is the world's reserve currency, backed by a large U.S. treasuries market, its role as the reference standard for the petrodollar system, and its linked eurodollar. Several countries use it as their official currency and in others it is the de facto currency. Since the end of World War II, the economy has achieved relatively steady growth, low unemployment and inflation, and rapid advances in technology.

Supply-side economics is a macroeconomic theory postulating that economic growth can be most effectively fostered by lowering taxes, decreasing regulation, and allowing free trade. According to supply-side economics theory, consumers will benefit from greater supply of goods and services at lower prices, and employment will increase. Supply-side fiscal policies are designed to increase aggregate supply, as opposed to aggregate demand, thereby expanding output and employment while lowering prices. Such policies are of several general varieties:

  1. Investments in human capital, such as education, healthcare, and encouraging the transfer of technologies and business processes, to improve productivity. Encouraging globalized free trade via containerization is a major recent example.
  2. Tax reduction, to provide incentives to work, invest and take risks. Lowering income tax rates and eliminating or lowering tariffs are examples of such policies.
  3. Investments in new capital equipment and research and development (R&D), to further improve productivity. Allowing businesses to depreciate capital equipment more rapidly gives them an immediate financial incentive to invest in such equipment.
  4. Reduction in government regulations, to encourage business formation and expansion.
<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economic inequality</span> Distribution of income or wealth between different groups

Economic inequality is an umbrella term for a) income inequality or distribution of income, b) wealth inequality or distribution of wealth, and c) consumption inequality. Each of these can be measured between two or more nations, within a single nation, or between and within sub-populations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Income distribution</span> How a countrys total GDP is distributed amongst its population

In economics, income distribution covers how a country's total GDP is distributed amongst its population. Economic theory and economic policy have long seen income and its distribution as a central concern. Unequal distribution of income causes economic inequality which is a concern in almost all countries around the world.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Minimum wage in the United States</span>

In the United States, the minimum wage is set by U.S. labor law and a range of state and local laws. The first federal minimum wage was instituted in the National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933, signed into law by President Franklin D. Roosevelt, but later found to be unconstitutional. In 1938, the Fair Labor Standards Act established it at 25¢ an hour. Its purchasing power peaked in 1968, at $1.60. In 2009, Congress increased it to $7.25 per hour with the Fair Minimum Wage Act of 2007, and has not increased it since.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Income inequality in the United States</span>

Income inequality has fluctuated considerably in the United States since measurements began around 1915, moving in an arc between peaks in the 1920s and 2000s, with a 30-year period of relatively lower inequality between 1950 and 1980.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Wealth inequality in the United States</span>

The inequality of wealth has substantially increased in the United States in recent decades. Wealth commonly includes the values of any homes, automobiles, personal valuables, businesses, savings, and investments, as well as any associated debts.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Middle-class squeeze</span> Decline in middle-class real wages and increase in economic inequality

The middle-class squeeze refers to negative trends in the standard of living and other conditions of the middle class of the population. Increases in wages fail to keep up with inflation for middle-income earners, leading to a relative decline in real wages, while at the same time, the phenomenon fails to have a similar effect on the top wage earners. People belonging to the middle class find that inflation in consumer goods and the housing market prevent them from maintaining a middle-class lifestyle, undermining aspirations of upward mobility.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Great Compression</span>

The Great Compression refers to the period of substantial wage compression in the United States that began in the early 1940s. During that time, economic inequality as shown by wealth distribution and income distribution between the rich and poor became much smaller than it had been in preceding time periods. The term was reportedly coined by Claudia Goldin and Robert Margo in a 1992 paper, and is a takeoff on the Great Depression, an event during which the Great Compression started.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Unemployment in the United States</span> Explanation of unemployment in the United States, presently and historically

Unemployment in the United States discusses the causes and measures of U.S. unemployment and strategies for reducing it. Job creation and unemployment are affected by factors such as economic conditions, global competition, education, automation, and demographics. These factors can affect the number of workers, the duration of unemployment, and wage levels.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Progressivity in United States income tax</span> Overview of tax rates

In general, the United States federal income tax is progressive, as rates of tax generally increase as taxable income increases, at least with respect to individuals that earn wage income. As a group, the lowest earning workers, especially those with dependents, pay no income taxes and may actually receive a small subsidy from the federal government.

In the United States, despite the efforts of equality proponents, income inequality persists among races and ethnicities. Asian Americans have the highest median income, followed by White Americans, Hispanic Americans, African Americans, and Native Americans. A variety of explanations for these differences have been proposed—such as differing access to education, two parent home family structure, high school dropout rates and experience of discrimination and deep-seated and systemic anti-Black racism—and the topic is highly controversial.

Tax policy and economic inequality in the United States discusses how tax policy affects the distribution of income and wealth in the United States. Income inequality can be measured before- and after-tax; this article focuses on the after-tax aspects. Income tax rates applied to various income levels and tax expenditures primarily drive how market results are redistributed to impact the after-tax inequality. After-tax inequality has risen in the United States markedly since 1980, following a more egalitarian period following World War II.

Political debates about the United States federal budget discusses some of the more significant U.S. budgetary debates of the 21st century. These include the causes of debt increases, the impact of tax cuts, specific events such as the United States fiscal cliff, the effectiveness of stimulus, and the impact of the Great Recession, among others. The article explains how to analyze the U.S. budget as well as the competing economic schools of thought that support the budgetary positions of the major parties.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Great Divergence (inequality)</span> Period of growing economic inequality

The Great Divergence is a term given to a period, starting in the late 1970s, during which income differences drastically increased in the United States and, to a lesser extent, in other countries. The term originated with the Nobel laureate, Princeton economist and The New York Times columnist Paul Krugman, and is a reference to the "Great Compression", an earlier era in the 1930s and the 1940s when incomes became more equal in the US and elsewhere.

Economic globalization is one of the three main dimensions of globalization commonly found in academic literature, with the two others being political globalization and cultural globalization, as well as the general term of globalization. Economic globalization refers to the widespread international movement of goods, capital, services, technology and information. It is the increasing economic integration and interdependence of national, regional, and local economies across the world through an intensification of cross-border movement of goods, services, technologies and capital. Economic globalization primarily comprises the globalization of production, finance, markets, technology, organizational regimes, institutions, corporations, and people.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Causes of unemployment in the United States</span> Overview of some possible causes of unemployment in the United States

Job creation and unemployment are affected by factors such as aggregate demand, global competition, education, automation, and demographics. These factors can affect the number of workers, the duration of unemployment, and wage rates.

The economic policy of the Donald Trump administration was characterized by the individual and corporate tax cuts, attempts to repeal the Affordable Care Act ("Obamacare"), trade protectionism, deregulation focused on the energy and financial sectors, and responses to the COVID-19 pandemic.

References

  1. Chart was made using data initially published as Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez (2003), Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 2003, 1–39. Data (and updates) shown at http://inequality.org/income-inequality
  2. "US Census Bureau. (2001). Historical Income Tables – Income Equality". Archived from the original on July 10, 2009. Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  3. "Weinberg, D. H. (June 1996). A Brief Look At Postwar U.S. Income Inequality. US Census Bureau" (PDF). Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  4. "Burtless, G. (January 11, 200). Has U.S. Income Inequality Really Increased?. The Brookings Institution" . Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  5. Gilbert, Dennis (2002). American Class Structure in an Age of Growing Inequality. Wadsworth.
  6. Beeghley, Leonard (2004). The Structure of Social Stratification in the United States. Boston, MD: Pearson, Allyn & Bacpn.
  7. Piketty, Thomas (2014). Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Belknap Press. ISBN   067443000X "The Explosion of US Inequality after 1980": pp. 294–96.
  8. 1 2 Weeks, J. (2007). Inequality Trends in Some Developed OECD countries. In J. K. S. & J. Baudot (Ed.), Flat World, Big Gaps (159–74). New York: ZED Books (published in association with the United Nations).
  9. Income distribution and poverty – OECD. OECD
  10. 1 2 Richard Wolff (October 26, 2011). How the 1% got richer, while the 99% got poorer. The Guardian. Retrieved October 6, 2014
  11. Congressional Budget Office: "Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007". October 2011. p. 13
  12. Congressional Budget Office: "Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007". October 2011. p. xi
  13. Yellen, J. L. (November 6, 2006). "Economic Inequality in the United States". University of California, Irvine: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  14. "The rich, the poor and the growing gap between them" . The Economist. June 15, 2006. Archived from the original on February 19, 2018.
  15. 1 2 3 4 Krugman, Paul (October 20, 2002). "For Richer". The New York Times.
  16. the superstar hypothesis was coined by the Chicago economist Sherwin Rosen) used the example of the passing of the hundreds of comedians that made a modest living at live shows in the borscht belt and other places in bygone days that have been replaced by a handful of superstar TV comedians.
  17. Autor, David; Dorn, David; Katz, Lawrence F; Patterson, Christina; Van Reenen, John (2020). "The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms*". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 135 (2): 645–709. doi:10.1093/qje/qjaa004. hdl: 10.1093/qje/qjaa004 . ISSN   0033-5533.
  18. 1 2 Cassidy, John (November 18, 2013). "American Inequality in Six Charts" via www.newyorker.com.
  19. Krugman, Paul (January 12, 2009). The Conscience of a Liberal. W. W. Norton & Company. p. 34. ISBN   978-0-393-06711-8., estimate by economist George Borjas
  20. 1 2 Krugman, Paul (2007). The Conscience of a Liberal. W.W. Norton Company, Inc. ISBN   978-0-393-06069-0.
  21. 1 2 "CEO Pay Continues to Rise as Typical Workers Are Paid Less". Economic Policy Institute.
  22. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Yosif, Michael Brill, Corey Holman, Chris Morris, Ronjoy Raichoudhary, and Noah. "Understanding the labor productivity and compensation gap : Beyond the Numbers: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics". www.bls.gov.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  23. "BLS-Fleck, Glaser, and Sprague-Visual Essay: Compensation-Productivity Gap-January 2011" (PDF).
  24. 1 2 "SOF/Heyman | The Society of Fellows and Heyman Center for the Humanities". SOF/Heyman.
  25. "The Left and Right Stumble on Globalization". Bloomberg.com. June 27, 2016. Retrieved October 10, 2020.
  26. "Google". www.google.com.
  27. 1 2 "The United States of Inequality, Entry 7: Trade Didn't Create Inequality, and Then It Did," by Timothy Noah (September 14, 2010)
  28. "Trade and Wages, Reconsidered", by Paul Krugman (February 2008)
  29. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 "The United States of Inequality. Entry 9: How the Decline in K–12 Education Enriches College Graduates," by Timothy Noah, Slate.com (September 15, 2010)
  30. Surowiecki, James (August 12, 2013). "The Pay Is Too Damn Low". The New Yorker.
  31. Smith, Noah (January 6, 2014.). The Dark Side of Globalization: Why Seattle's 1999 Protesters Were Right. The Atlantic. Retrieved January 10, 2014.
  32. No Jobs from Trade Pacts: The Trans-Pacific Partnership Could Be Much Worse than the Over-Hyped Korea Deal. Economic Policy Institute . July 18, 2013
  33. Gains from Trade? The Net Effect of the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement on U.S. Wages Archived September 10, 2013, at archive.today . Center for Economic and Policy Research . September 2013
  34. "Emmanuel Saez-Income and Wealth Inequality:Evidence and Policy Implications-October 2014" (PDF).
  35. Thomas Piketty Is Wrong: America Will Never Look Like a Jane Austen Novel, Eric Posner and Glen Weyl, New Republic, 2014
  36. It's the Market: The Broad-Based Rise in the Return to Top Talent Steven N. Kaplan and Joshua Rauh Archived September 5, 2014, at the Wayback Machine , 2014
  37. Ed Dolan, Globalization and Inequality: Is there a Superstar Effect, and if so, What does it Mean?
  38. "Why We're In A New Gilded Age", Paul Krugman, New York Review of Books, May 8, 2014
  39. Irwin, Neil (June 16, 2017). "The Amazon-Walmart Showdown That Explains the Modern Economy" via NYTimes.com.
  40. 1 2 "US Census Bureau. (2006). Personal income and educational attainment". Archived from the original on October 9, 2006. Retrieved September 24, 2006.
  41. "US Census Bureau. (2006). Educational attainment and median household income". Archived from the original on September 3, 2006. Retrieved September 24, 2006.
  42. 1 2 Levine, Rhonda (1998). Social Class and Stratification . Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield. 0-8476-8543-8.
  43. Zweig, M. (2004). The What's Class Got To Do With It? Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
  44. 1 2 3 4 "Stoops, N. (June, 2004). Educational Attainment in the United States: 2003. US Census Bureau" (PDF). Retrieved June 21, 2007.
  45. "Rector, R., & Herderman Jr., R. (August 24, 2004). Two Americas, One Rich, One Poor? Understanding Income Inequality In the United States. Heritage Foundation". Archived from the original on June 13, 2007. Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  46. 1 2 3 "US Census Bureau. (2006). Selected Characteristics of Households, by Total Money Income in 2005". Archived from the original on June 26, 2007. Retrieved June 21, 2007.
  47. 1 2 3 "US Census Bureau. (2006). Household income quintiles and top 5%". Archived from the original on January 4, 2007. Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  48. Nichole Stoops, US Census Bureau, August 2004
  49. 1 2 3 4 5 Noah, Timothy (2012). The Great Divergence. Bloomsbury Press. ISBN   978-1-60819-635-7.
  50. "Science Magazine - 23 May 2014 - page71". www.sciencemagazinedigital.org.
  51. Hart, Betty; Todd Risley (1995). "The Early Catastrophe". American Educator. American Federation of Teachers. ISSN   0148-432X.
  52. Creaser, Richard (January 22, 2014). "NECAP scores can illustrate achievement gap". The Chronicle. Barton, Vermont. pp. 1A, 22A–24A.
  53. "On Income Stagnation". November 12, 2014.
  54. Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson (2011) Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington made the rich richer – and turned its back on the middle class.
  55. Dictionary of economics online
  56. Economic Report of the President 1997 Archived June 5, 2013, at the Wayback Machine mentions "colloquium on this topic at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York" (1995?)
  57. Experts' Consensus on Earnings Inequality Archived June 5, 2013, at the Wayback Machine . Economic Report of the President 1997
  58. 1 2 "The New York Times. (June 7, 2007). The Rewards of Education". The New York Times. June 9, 2007. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  59. "Only advanced degree-holders saw wage gains in last decade". Archived from the original on December 4, 2013.
  60. Bernstein, Jared (November 18, 2013). "Inequality's Roots: Beyond Technology". The New York Times. Retrieved November 22, 2013.
  61. 1 2 "The United States of Inequality, Entry 4: Did Computers Create Inequality?" by Timothy Noah, Slate (September 8, 2010)
  62. 1 2 "US Census Bureau. (2006). People 18 Years Old and Over, by Total Money Earnings in 2005, Age, Race, Hispanic Origin, and Sex". Archived from the original on September 29, 2006. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  63. 1 2 Schaeffer, Richard (2005). Racial and Ethnic Groups. New York, NY: Prentice Hall. 013192897X.
  64. Lukas, Carrie (April 3, 2007). "A Bargain At 77 Cents To a Dollar". The Washington Post. Retrieved May 5, 2010.
  65. Chapman, Steve (August 19, 2010). "The Truth About the Pay Gap".
  66. "US Census Bureau 2005 Economic survey, racial income distribution". Archived from the original on July 7, 2006. Retrieved June 29, 2006.
  67. Hine, Darlene; William C. Hine; Stanley Harrold (2006). The African American Odyssey. Boston, MA: Pearson. 0-12-182217-3.
  68. "People 18 Years Old and Over, by Total Money Income in 2005, Work Experience in 2005, Age, Race, Hispanic Origin, and Sex". Archived from the original on September 29, 2006. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  69. Asian-American Parenting and Academic Success Archived April 5, 2012, at the Wayback Machine . Miller-McCune. December 13, 2010
  70. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Highlights of Women's Earnings in 2009. Report 1025, June 2010.
  71. 1 2 "US Census Bureau. (2006). People by Median Income and Sex: 1953 to 2005". Archived from the original on November 2, 2007. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  72. "Digest of Education Statistics, 2007". nces.ed.gov.
  73. "Digest of Education Statistics, 2007". nces.ed.gov.
  74. "US Census Bureau. (2006). Income distribution among Asian males, age 25+ according to educational attainment". Archived from the original on May 11, 2011. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  75. 1 2 "US Census Bureau. (2006). Income distribution among Hispanic females, age 25+ according to educational attainment". Archived from the original on December 6, 2007. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  76. "US Census Bureau. (2006). Personal income distribution among Asian males, age 25+ according to educational attainment". Archived from the original on May 11, 2011. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  77. "Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Trends in Poverty and Inequality among Hispanics, June 2011" (PDF).
  78. "US Census Bureau. (2006). People (Both Sexes Combined – All Races) by Median and Mean Income: 1974 to 2005" . Retrieved June 23, 2007.
  79. 1 2 Data from Chetty, Raj; Jackson, Matthew O.; Kuchler, Theresa; Stroebel, Johannes; et al. (August 1, 2022). "Social capital I: measurement and associations with economic mobility". Nature. 608 (7921): 108–121. Bibcode:2022Natur.608..108C. doi:10.1038/s41586-022-04996-4. PMC   9352590 . PMID   35915342. Charted in Leonhardt, David (August 1, 2022). "'Friending Bias' / A large new study offers clues about how lower-income children can rise up the economic ladder". The New York Times. Archived from the original on August 1, 2022.
  80. Economic Mobility: Is the American Dream Alive and Well? Isabel Sawhill & John E. Morton. February 21, 2007. Economic Mobility Project, Washington, D.C.. December 4, 2007. Archived February 9, 2012, at the Wayback Machine
  81. Thompson, William; Joseph Hickey (2005). Society in Focus. Boston, MA: Pearson.
  82. Lazonick, William (September 1, 2014). "Profits Without Prosperity" via hbr.org.
  83. "BEA-GDP Press Release-Q3 2014 "Advance Estimate". October 30, 2014". Archived from the original on June 8, 2017. Retrieved March 9, 2018.
  84. Cox, Jeff (November 11, 2014). "Stock buybacks expected to jump 18% in 2015". CNBC.
  85. Meyerson, Harold (August 26, 2014). "In corporations, it's owner-take-all" via www.washingtonpost.com.
  86. 1 2 "The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2010". The US Congressional Budget Office (CBO). December 4, 2013. Retrieved January 6, 2014.
  87. Picchi, Aimee (October 17, 2019). "America's richest 400 families now pay a lower tax rate than the middle class". CBS News. Archived from the original on May 11, 2024. (Chart labeled "Effective tax rates by income".) Analysis by economists Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman.
  88. "High-income Americans pay most income taxes, but enough to be 'fair'?". Pew Center. Retrieved November 30, 2016.
  89. Webster (4b): increasing in rate as the base increases (a progressive tax)
  90. American Heritage Archived February 9, 2009, at the Wayback Machine (6). Increasing in rate as the taxable amount increases.
  91. Britannica Concise Encyclopedia: Tax levied at a rate that increases as the quantity subject to taxation increases.
  92. Princeton University WordNet [ permanent dead link ]: (n) progressive tax (any tax in which the rate increases as the amount subject to taxation increases)
  93. Sommerfeld, Ray M., Silvia A. Madeo, Kenneth E. Anderson, Betty R. Jackson (1992), Concepts of Taxation, Dryden Press: Fort Worth, TX
  94. Causes of income inequality in the United States , p. 104, at Google Books OECD Publishing, ISBN   978-92-64-04418-0, 2008, pp. 103, 104.
  95. Congressional Budget Office: "Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007". October 2011. p. 20 and figure 12.
  96. 1 2 3 4 5 Noah, Timothy. "Can We Blame Income Inequality on Republicans" in the multi-part series "The United States of Inequality." Slate, September 9, 2010.
  97. "New CBO Data Show Income Inequality Continues to Widen After-Tax-Income for Top 1 Percent Rose by $146,000 in 2004," by Aviva Aron-Dine and Arloc Sherman, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities (January 23, 2007)
  98. How Progressive is the U.S. Federal Tax System? A Historical and International Perspective Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, p. 23
  99. Silliman, B. R. (2008). Will the next president reform the tax code? A historical examination. The CPA Journal, 78(11), 23–27.
  100. "How Progressive is the U.S. Federal Tax System? A Historical and International Perspective" (PDF).
  101. "What Do Tax Rates' Ups and Downs Mean for Economic Growth?" PBS NewsHour (Dec. 12, 2011.) Retrieved on 2013-07-29.
  102. Bellafiore, Robert. Mauro, Madison. "The Top 1 Percent's Tax Rates Over Time." March 5, 2019. https://taxfoundation.org/top-1-percent-tax-rate/
  103. Kocieniewski, David (January 18, 2012). "Since 1980s, the Kindest of Tax Cuts for the Rich". The New York Times. Retrieved January 21, 2012.
  104. "Effects of Lower Capital Gains Taxes on Economic Growth | Congressional Budget Office". www.cbo.gov.
  105. Dickinson, Tom (November 9, 2011). "How the GOP Became the Party of the Rich". Rolling Stone. Retrieved January 2, 2012.
  106. 1 2 3 Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, "How Progressive is the U.S. Federal Tax System? A Historical and International Perspective". Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 21, Number 1 – Winter 2007
  107. Stiglitz, Joseph (June 2012). "We've been brainwashed". Salon Magazine . Retrieved November 17, 2014.
  108. "Even after exploiting all possible deductions and credits, the typical high-income taxpayer during the Great Prosperity paid a federal tax of well over 50 percent of his earnings." Clinton Administration Secretary of labor Robert Reich In his book Aftershock: The Next Economy and America's Future
  109. Krugman, Paul (1995). Peddling Prosperity: Economic Sense and Nonsense in an Age of Diminished Expectations. New York: W. W. Norton & Company. p. 155. ISBN   978-0-393-31292-8 . Retrieved February 3, 2012.
  110. "FactChecking Obama's Budget Speech". FactCheck.org. April 15, 2011. Retrieved January 4, 2011.
  111. Thomas L. Hungerford "Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers Between 1996 and 2006: The Role of Labor Income, Capital Income, and Tax Policy." Congressional Research Service, December 29, 2011. http://taxprof.typepad.com/files/crs-1.pdf
  112. 1 2 "The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes 2011". Congressional Budget Office, US Government. November 2014.
  113. "Richest 20 percent get half the overall savings from U.S. tax breaks, CBO says". The Washington Post .
  114. "The Distribution of Major Tax Expenditures in the Individual Income Tax System". CBO. May 29, 2013.
  115. 1 2 Krugman, Paul (December 17, 2015). "Challenging the Oligarchy" via www.nybooks.com.
  116. Leonhardt, David (July 7, 2023). "How Elba Makes a Living Wage". The New York Times. Archived from the original on July 8, 2023.
  117. "Union Members in 2007", US Bureau of Labor Statistics, January 25, 2008
  118. Card, David; Lemieux, Thomas; Riddell, W. Craig (2004). "Unions and wage inequality". Journal of Labor Research. 25 (4): 519–559. doi:10.1007/s12122-004-1011-z. S2CID   10343473.
  119. 1 2 3 4 The United States of Inequality, Entry 6: The Great Divergence and the death of organized labor. By Timothy Noah, Slate.com, September 12, 2010
  120. Florence Jaumotte and Carolina Osorio Buitron. Power from the People. Finance & Development. March 2015, Vol. 52, No. 1.
  121. Freeman, Richard B. (1980). "Unionism and the Dispersion of Wages" (PDF). Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 34 (1): 3–23. doi:10.1177/001979398003400101. S2CID   153456125.
  122. Card, David (2001). "The Effect of Unions on Wage Inequality in the U.S. Labor Market". Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 54 (2): 296–315. doi:10.1177/001979390105400206. S2CID   14183242.
  123. Western, Bruce; Rosenfeld, Jake (2011). "Unions, Norms, and the Rise in U.S. Wage Inequality". American Sociological Review . 76 (4): 513–37. doi:10.1177/0003122411414817. S2CID   18351034.
  124. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012). The price of inequality: how today's divided society endangers our future. New York: W.W. Norton & Company. ISBN   9780393088694.
  125. Stiglitz, Joseph; Greenwald, Bruce C. (2014). Creating a learning society: a new approach to growth, development, and social progress. New York: Columbia University Press. ISBN   9780231152143.
  126. Rosenfeld, Jake (2014). What Unions No Longer Do. Harvard University Press. ISBN   0674725115
  127. Kristof, Nicholas (February 19, 2015). "Opinion | The Cost of a Decline in Unions". The New York Times . ISSN   0362-4331 . Retrieved December 8, 2019. I disdained unions as bringing corruption, nepotism and rigid work rules to the labor market, impeding the economic growth that ultimately makes a country strong. I was wrong. The abuses are real. But, as unions wane in American life, it's also increasingly clear that they were doing a lot of good in sustaining middle class life — especially the private-sector unions that are now dwindling."   ...   He's right. This isn't something you often hear a columnist say, but I'll say it again: I was wrong. At least in the private sector, we should strengthen unions, not try to eviscerate them.
  128. Greenhouse, Steven. Labor's Decline and Wage Inequality, The New York Times
  129. Michael Hiltzik (March 25, 2015). IMF agrees: Decline of union power has increased income inequality. Los Angeles Times. Retrieved March 26, 2015.
  130. Inequality and Institutions in 20th Century America Frank Levy and Peter Temin Revised June 27, 2007
  131. Jake Rosenfeld, What Unions No Longer Do, (Harvard University Press, 2014), ISBN   0674725115
  132. David Madland and Keith Miller (September 17, 2013). Latest Census Data Underscore How Important Unions Are for the Middle Class. Center for American Progress. Retrieved September 18, 2013.
  133. Tami Luhby (November 8, 2011). Global income inequality: Where the U.S. ranks. CNNMoney Retrieved September 2, 2013.
  134. Liz Alderman and Steven Greenhouse (October 27, 2014). Living Wages, Rarity for U.S. Fast-Food Workers, Served Up in Denmark. The New York Times. Retrieved October 29, 2014.
  135. "CIA. (June 14, 2007). United States: Economy. World Factbook" . Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  136. Archer, Robin (2007). Why Is There No Labor Party in the United States? Princeton University Press. ISBN   0691149348 Causes of income inequality in the United States , p. 1, at Google Books Retrieved November 23, 2013.
  137. Gordon Lafer (October 31, 2013). The Legislative Attack on American Wages and Labor Standards, 2011–2012. Economic Policy Institute. Retrieved October 31, 2013.
  138. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future (Kindle Locations 1148–1149). Norton. Kindle Edition.
  139. Kristal, Tali; Cohen, Yinon (March 23, 2016). "The causes of rising wage inequality: the race between institutions and technology". Socio-Economic Review : mww006. doi: 10.1093/ser/mww006 . ISSN   1475-1461.
  140. 1 2 Bartels, L. M. (2008). Unequal democracy: The political economy of the new gilded age. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  141. Kelly, N.J. (2009). The Politics of Income Inequality in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.
  142. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age by Larry Bartels (Princeton University Press: 2008)
  143. 1 2 Paul Ryan: Inequality, Take Two, Timothy Noah, The New Republic, November 18, 2011
  144. Income Growth Rates 1948–2005 under Democratic presidents and under Republican presidents. Graphics by Catherine Mulbrandon
  145. 1 2 Norris, Pippa; Inglehart, Ronald (February 11, 2019). Cultural Backlash: Trump, Brexit, and Authoritarian Populism . Cambridge University Press. pp. 134–139. doi:10.1017/9781108595841. ISBN   978-1-108-59584-1. S2CID   242313055.
  146. Broz, J. Lawrence; Frieden, Jeffry; Weymouth, Stephen (2021). "Populism in Place: The Economic Geography of the Globalization Backlash". International Organization. 75 (2): 464–494. doi: 10.1017/S0020818320000314 . ISSN   0020-8183.
  147. Mudde, Cas (2007). Populist Radical Right Parties in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp. 205–206. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511492037. ISBN   978-0-511-49203-7.
  148. Flaherty, Thomas M.; Rogowski, Ronald (2021). "Rising Inequality As a Threat to the Liberal International Order". International Organization. 75 (2): 495–523. doi: 10.1017/S0020818321000163 . ISSN   0020-8183.
  149. 1 2 3 Berman, Sheri (May 11, 2021). "The Causes of Populism in the West". Annual Review of Political Science. 24 (1): 71–88. doi: 10.1146/annurev-polisci-041719-102503 .
  150. Piketty, Thomas (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN   978-0-674-43000-6.
  151. Hacker, Jacob S. (2019). The great risk shift: the new economic insecurity and the decline of the American dream (Expanded & fully revised second ed.). New York, NY: Oxford University Press. ISBN   978-0-19-084414-1.
  152. Wolf, M. (December 3, 2019). "How to reform today's rigged capitalism". Financial Times. Archived from the original on December 10, 2022. Retrieved August 24, 2021.
  153. Dancygier, RM. (2010). Immigration and Conflict in Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  154. Klapsis, Antonis (December 2014). "Economic Crisis and Political Extremism in Europe: From the 1930s to the Present". European View. 13 (2): 189–198. doi: 10.1007/s12290-014-0315-5 .
  155. Funke, Manuel; Schularick, Moritz; Trebesch, Christoph (September 2016). "Going to extremes: Politics after financial crises, 1870–2014" (PDF). European Economic Review. 88: 227–260. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2016.03.006. S2CID   154426984.
  156. Gavin, Michael; Manger, Mark (2023). "Populism and de Facto Central Bank Independence". Comparative Political Studies. 56 (8): 1189–1223. doi:10.1177/00104140221139513. PMC   10251451 . PMID   37305061.
  157. Scheidel, Walter (2017). The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century. Princeton University Press. p.  416. ISBN   978-0691165028.
  158. Springer, Simon; Birch, Kean; MacLeavy, Julie, eds. (2016). The Handbook of Neoliberalism. Routledge. p.  144. ISBN   978-1138844001.
  159. Nikolaos Karagiannis, Zagros Madjd-Sadjadi, Swapan Sen (eds). The US Economy and Neoliberalism: Alternative Strategies and Policies. Routledge, 2013. ISBN   1138904910. p. 58
  160. More compensation heading to the very top: 1965–2009 Archived November 24, 2011, at the Wayback Machine . May 16, 2011.
  161. Winner-Take-All Politics, p.7
  162. Winner-Take-All Politics, pp. 115, 219, 228
  163. Winner-Take-All Politics, p. 66
  164. More compensation heading for the very top Archived September 4, 2012, at the Wayback Machine EPI 2010
  165. Krugman, Paul, The Conscience of a Liberal, W W Norton & Company, 2007, pp. 143–44
  166. Causes of income inequality in the United States at Google Books By Lucian Arye Bebchuk, Jesse M. Fried]
  167. Krugman, The Conscience of a Liberal, 2007, p. 145
  168. "The Broken Contract", By George Packer, Foreign Affairs , November/December 2011
  169. 1 2 The Great Divergence By Timothy Noah
  170. "Economist David Card-NBER Working Paper-Immigration and Inequality-2009" (PDF).
  171. "The United States of Inequality: Did the post-1965 immigration surge cause the Great Divergence?" by Timothy Noah (September 7, 2010)
  172. Smeeding, T. (2005). Public policy, economic inequality, and poverty: The United States in comparative perspective. Social Science Quarterly, 86, 956–83.
  173. "American politics, Democracy in America: Winner-Take-All Politics. It's a pretty good book." The Economist (September 21, 2010)
  174. Winner-Take-All Politics, p. 39, Figure 3
  175. Krugman, P. (2007). The conscience of a liberal. New York: W. W. Norton.
  176. An Epidemic of Wage Theft Is Costing Workers Hundreds of Millions of Dollars a Year. Economic Policy Institute. Retrieved June 13, 2015.
  177. Capitalism vs Corporatism - Edmund Phelps Columbia University. January 11, 2010).
  178. Phelps, Edmund (August 25, 2013). Mass Flourishing: How Grassroots Innovation Created Jobs, Challenge, and Change (1st ed.). Princeton University Press. p. 392. ISBN   978-0691158983.
  179. Glaeser, Edward (October 18, 2013). "Book Review: 'Mass Flourishing' by Edmund Phelps" via www.wsj.com.
  180. "The CFO Alliance Executive Compensation Survey 2013" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on October 13, 2014. Retrieved November 15, 2014.
  181. Krugman, Paul (November 24, 2011). "Opinion | We Are the 99.9%" via NYTimes.com.
  182. Thompson, Derek (March 30, 2014). "How You, I, and Everyone Got the Top 1 Percent All Wrong". The Atlantic.
  183. The Distribution of US Wealth, Capital Income and Returns since 1913, Emmanuel Saez, Gabriel Zucman, March 2014
  184. DeMuth, Phil. "Are You Rich Enough? The Terrible Tragedy Of Income Inequality Among The 1%". Forbes.
  185. Goodhart, Charles; Erfurth, Philipp (November 3, 2014). "Monetary policy and long-term trends".
  186. FRED Database-Income Measures vs GDP-Retrieved November 6, 2014
  187. "Harness market forces to share prosperity".
  188. Mian, Atif; Sufi, Amir (2014). House of Debt. University of Chicago. ISBN   978-0-226-08194-6.
  189. "Unbottled Gini, Unbottled Gini" via The Economist.
  190. Dean, Jodi (2012). The Communist Horizon. Verso. p. 123. ISBN   978-1844679546. Pursued through policies of privatization, deregulation, and financialization, and buttressed by an ideology of private property, free markets, and free trade, neoliberalism has entailed cuts in taxes for the rich and cuts in protections and benefits for workers and the poor, resulting in an exponential increase in inequality.
  191. Neoliberalism: Oversold? - IMF FINANCE & DEVELOPMENT June 2016 • Volume 53 • Number 2
  192. IMF: The last generation of economic policies may have been a complete failure. Business Insider. May 2016.
  193. Haymes, Stephen; Vidal de Haymes, Maria; Miller, Reuben, eds. (2015). The Routledge Handbook of Poverty in the United States. London: Routledge. p.  7. ISBN   978-0415673440. Neoliberalism represents a reassertion of the liberal political economic beliefs of the 19th century in the contemporary era.
  194. Yvonne Roberts (July 13, 2012). The Price of Inequality by Joseph Stiglitz – review. The Guardian. Retrieved March 30, 2015.
  195. Gérard Duménil and Dominique Lévy (2004). Capital Resurgent: Roots of the Neoliberal Revolution. Harvard University Press. ISBN   0674011589
    • "The advent of economic neoliberalism in the 1980s triggered a shift in the world economy. In the three decades following World War II, now considered a golden age of capitalism, economic growth was high and income inequality decreasing. But in the mid-1970s this social compact was broken as the world economy entered the stagflation crisis, following a decline in the profitability of capital. This crisis opened a new phase of stagnating growth and wages, and unemployment. Interest rates as well as dividend flows rose, and income inequality widened."
  196. David Coburn. Income inequality, social cohesion and the health status of populations: the role of neo-liberalism. Elsevier, Volume 51, Issue 1, July 2000, pp. 135–46. Retrieved October 7, 2014.
  197. 1 2 Vicente Navarro, ed. Neoliberalism, Globalization, and Inequalities: Consequences for Health and Quality of Life. Baywood Publishing Company, 2007. ISBN   0895033380 1-6.
  198. Lyon-Callo, Vincent (2004). Inequality, Poverty, and Neoliberal Governance: Activist Ethnography in the Homeless Sheltering Industry Archived August 5, 2018, at the Wayback Machine . University of Toronto Press. ISBN   1442600861. p. 14.
  199. [190] [10] [191] [192] [193] [194] [195] [196] [197] [198]
  200. Springer, Simon; Birch, Kean; MacLeavy, Julie, eds. (2016). The Handbook of Neoliberalism. Routledge. p.  2. ISBN   978-1138844001.
  201. David Moberg (June 6, 2014). Privatizing Government Services Doesn't Only Hurt Public Workers. In These Times. Retrieved October 7, 2014.
  202. Thomas I. Palley (May 5, 2004). From Keynesianism to Neoliberalism: Shifting Paradigms in Economics. Foreign Policy in Focus. Retrieved November 11, 2014.
  203. 1 2 David M Kotz, The Rise and Fall of Neoliberal Capitalism, (Harvard University Press, 2015), ISBN   0674725654. p. 43
  204. Anderson, Elizabeth (2023). Hijacked: How Neoliberalism Turned the Work Ethic against Workers and How Workers Can Take It Back. Cambridge University Press. p. xi. ISBN   978-1009275439.
  205. Saez, Emmanuel (September 3, 2013). "Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States". UC Berkeley. Retrieved September 18, 2014.
  206. Stephen Haymes, Maria Vidal de Haymes and Reuben Miller (eds), The Routledge Handbook of Poverty in the United States, (London: Routledge, 2015), ISBN   0415673445, p. 8.
  207. Bittman, Mark (December 13, 2014). "Is It Bad Enough Yet?". The New York Times . Retrieved August 3, 2018.
  208. Henry Farrell (July 18, 2014). The free market is an impossible utopia. The Washington Post. Retrieved October 10, 2014; see also: Fred Block and Margaret R. Somers. The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl Polanyi's Critique. Harvard University Press, 2014. ISBN   0674050711
  209. Schmitt, John and Ben Zipperer (2006). "Is the U.S. a Good Model for Reducing Social Exclusion in Europe?" Center for Economic and Policy Research. Retrieved October 8, 2014.
  210. Hopkin, Jonathan (2020). "American Nightmare: How Neoliberalism Broke US Democracy". Anti-System Politics: The Crisis of Market Liberalism in Rich Democracies. Oxford University Press. pp. 87–88. doi:10.1093/oso/9780190699765.003.0004. ISBN   978-0190699765.
  211. Baker, Dean. 2006. "Increasing Inequality in the United States." Post-autistic Economics Review 40.
  212. Howell, David R. and Mamadou Diallo. 2007. "Charting U.S. Economic Performance with Alternative Labor Market Indicators: The Importance of Accounting for Job Quality." SCEPA Working Paper 2007-6.

Further reading