Marianne Bertrand

Last updated
Marianne Bertrand
Bornc.1970 (age 5354)
Belgium
Nationality Belgian
Academic career
Field Social economics
Institutions Princeton University
University of Chicago Brussels University
Alma mater Harvard University
Université libre de Bruxelles
Doctoral
advisor
Lawrence F. Katz [1]
AwardsSherwin Rosen Award for Outstanding Contributions to Labor Economics(2012)
Elaine Bennett Research Prize (2004) [2]
Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences
Information at IDEAS / RePEc

Marianne Bertrand (born c. 1970) is a Belgian economist who currently works as Chris P. Dialynas Distinguished Service Professor of Economics and Willard Graham Faculty Scholar at the University of Chicago's Booth School of Business. Bertrand belongs to the world's most prominent labour economists in terms of research, [3] and has been awarded the 2004 Elaine Bennett Research Prize [4] and the 2012 Sherwin Rosen Prize for Outstanding Contributions in the Field of Labor Economics. [5] She is a research fellow of the National Bureau of Economic Research, and the IZA Institute of Labor Economics.

Contents

Early life and education

Bertrand earned a B.A. in economics and a M.Sc. in econometrics from the Free University of Brussels in 1991 and 1992. Thereafter, she did a Ph.D. in economics at Harvard University.

Career

After her graduation in 1998, Bertrand became an assistant professor of economics and public affairs at Princeton University's Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs but left for the University of Chicago's Booth School of Business in 2000. There, she was promoted to full professor in 2003, followed by the positions of Fred G. Steingraber/A. T. Kearney Professor of Economics and Chris. P. Dialynas Professor Economics. In addition to her academic position, Bertrand maintains affiliations with the Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab, where she is a member of the Board of Directors and currently co-chairs J-PAL's Labor Markets sector, [6] the Russell Sage Foundation, IZA, NBER, and CEPR. At Chicago, she is involved as Faculty Director in the Inclusive Economy Lab of the university's Urban Labs as well as the Booth Rustandy Center for Social Sector Innovation, Booth's social impact hub. She also has performed editorial duties for the American Economic Review , Quarterly Journal of Economics , American Economic Journal: Applied Economics , Economic Journal , and the Journal of the European Economic Association . [7]

Research

Bertrand's research interests include econometric methodology, labour economics, corporate governance and development economics. Her most-cited article is her 2004 article with Esther Duflo and Sendil Mullainathan, "How Much Should We Trust Differences-In-Differences Estimates?" [8] In most of her research she uses economic experiments, often in collaboration with her frequent co-author Sendhil Mullainathan. According to IDEAS/RePEc, Bertrand ranked in September 2018 157th in terms of research among 54,233 registered economists (i.e., among the top 0.3%) [9] and 5th among 10,406 female economists (among the top 0.05%) [10] As of August 2024 her rank increased to 83rd overall. [11]

Research on labour economics, discrimination and gender gaps

One key area of Bertrand's research is labour economics, in particular racial and gender discrimination. Together with Sendhil Mullainathan, she finds that the introduction of antitakeover legislation, which shield companies somewhat from competition, in the 1980s raised wages by 1–2%, thus suggesting that managers have some discretion in wage setting. [12] In a seminal contribution to research on racial labour market discrimination, Bertrand and Mullainathan manipulate perceived race on fictitious resumes sent in reply to help-wanted ads by using Afro-American- or Caucasian-sounding names and observe that "white names" receive 50% more callbacks for interviews, a finding that holds robustly across occupations, industries, firm sizes and controls for social class. [13] Relatedly, Bertrand, Mullainathan and Dolly Chugh have argued for the existence of implicit discrimination, which – unlike taste-based or statistical discrimination – is unintentional and of which the discriminator is unaware. [14] In another exploration of racial discrimination, Bertrand, Mullainathan and David Abrams find that judges in Illinois vary in the degree to which race influences their sentencing, with smaller gaps between white and Afro-American incarceration rates for Afro-American judges and judges passing comparatively many incarceration sentences also being disproportionately likely to sentence Afro-Americans to jail. [15]

Studying the impact of entry regulation on job creation in France with Francis Kramarz, Bertrand finds that regional zoning boards' tendency to deter the creation or extension of retail stores increased retailer concentration and slowed down employment growth. [16] In another study of the impact of infra-industry competition on wages, Bertrand finds that growth in import competition makes workers' wages more sensitive to the current unemployment rate and less sensitive to the unemployment rate that prevailed at the time they were hired, thus suggesting that import competition may erode the implicit contracts between employers and their employees. [17]

Analysing the gender gap with Kevin Hallock, Bertrand observes that from 1992 to 1997 only 2.5% of top executives in US firms were women and that they earned on average 45% less than men, with up to 75% of that gap being explained by differences in the size of the managed firms and women's lower likelihood to be CEO, chair or president, though she also finds that female participation in top executive positions nearly tripled during that period; nonetheless, Bertrand and Hallock stress that gender discrimination via segregation or unequal promotion cannot be ruled out. [18] Further exploring the issue of gender pay gaps with Claudia Goldin and Lawrence F. Katz, Bertrand finds that although the earnings of male and female MBAs are nearly identical at the beginning of their careers, ten years later, male earnings are almost 60 log points higher, with most of the gap being explained by differences in pre-MBA training, career interruptions and weekly hours, the latter two being mostly due to motherhood. [19] Another major contribution to the role of gender in the labour market is Bertrand's 2011 chapter in the Handbook of Labor Economics, which reviews the potential of psychological and socio-psychological factors in explaining gender differences in labour market outcomes. [20] More recently, in research with Emir Kamenica and Jessica Pan, Bertrand has found that the distribution of wives' share of household income drops sharply just after 50%, which she attributes to gender norms averse to the husband earning less than his wife, a norm that in turn affects the formation of marriages, wives' labour force participation and their income conditional on working, marriage satisfaction, divorce rates, and the division of household chores. [21] Relatedly, Bertrand and Pan have also explored the gender gap in disruptive behaviour, finding that boys' propensity to disruptive behaviour – unlike girls' – seems to be extremely responsive to parental inputs, which are substantially worse in broken families, whereas early school environment has little impact. [22]

Another interesting research pertaining to gender gap is about effect of board quotas on female labor force in Norway. She found that after Norway passed the law to have at least 40% women representation in board meetings, there were no significant impacts to the broader female population in the country. They found that this bill benefited young female business graduates the most. The overall conclusion after seven years was that this law had minimum impact on the larger society of women, expect for those who were actually on the board. [23]

Research on corporate governance, family firms and finance

Another major area of Bertrand's research is corporate governance. Together with Mullainathan, Bertrand has researched the determinants of CEO pay, contrasting the contracting view – shareholders set CEO contracts in such a way as to limit moral hazard – with the skimming view – CEOs set their own pay by manipulation the compensation committee to skim as much as possible. [24] In line with the skimming view, they find that CEO pay responds just as much to luck – shocks to the firm performance that are objectively beyond their control – as to developments over which they have control, with the sensitivity to luck being generally higher in firms with poor corporate governance. [25] Moreover, Bertrand and Mullainathan find that the more managers' firms are sheltered from competition, e.g. antitakeover laws, the more wages rise and productivity and profitability fall, possibly due to decreases in the destruction of old and the creation of new plants, suggesting that managers may prefer stability to empire building. [26] Together with Antoinette Schoar, Bertrand has investigated the effect of managers on firm policies in the U.S., finding that a large share of differences between firms' investment, financial, and organizational practices are due to differences in their managers and, more importantly, their management style, with older managers generally being more conservative and managers with MBA degrees being generally more aggressive in terms of corporate decisions. [27] In work with Schoar and David Thesmar, Bertrand observes that after the deregulation of banking in France in 1985, banks became less willing to bail out firms with poor performance and firms being more dependent on banks became more likely to restructure, with rising rates of job and asset reallocation, higher allocative efficiency, and a less concentrated banking sector, an observation in line with Schumpeterian processes of creative destruction. [28] Finally, together with Adair Morse, Bertrand succeeds in decreasing the take-up of highly costly payday loans by 11% over a four-month period by making borrowers think about the dollar fees accruing due to the loans' roll-over, suggesting a role for information disclosure policies to remedy payday borrowing. [29]

Bertrand and Schoar have also conducted research on the role of family for family enterprises, finding that family values tend to be associated with lower economic development – though differently than trust – and more family firms are fairly stable over time, do not react much to economic changes, and do not appear to reflect weak formal institutions. [30] In further research on this topic in Thailand with Simon Johnson and Krislert Samphantharak, Bertrand and Schoar find family involvement in the ownership of family businesses to increase in family size, though firm performance decreases the more the founders' sons become involved, possibly because of a "race to the bottom", wherein fearing the dilution of ownership and control over the business group, the descendants attempt to tunnel resources out of the group's firms. [31] These results are matched by Bertrand and Mullainathan's earlier research on business groups in India, which also finds significant amounts of tunneling, especially via nonoperating components of profit. [32]

Research on development economics

A third area of Bertrand's research concerns development economics. One of Bertrand's most important contributions to this area is the development (together with Mullainathan and Eldar Shafir) of a view on poverty that emphasizes neither the role of a culture of poverty or of significant differences between the psychology and attitudes of poor and rich people, but rather highlights that the economic consequences of common biases are disproportionately large for poor people precisely because they are poor and thus have little margin for error. [33] They thus argue for the use of insights from behavioural economics and marketing to help poor people make decisions, e.g. by making participation in programs aimed at the poor simple and by investing into the marketing of these programs to increase their outreach. [34] With Mullainathan and Douglas Miller, Bertrand has also studied the allocation of resources within extended families in the wake of South Africa's pension program, finding the labour supply of prime-age individuals to drop sharply when elderly household members become eligible for pensions, with the drop being larger if the pensioner is a woman, if the non-pensioners are themselves old, and if they are male, the drop being largest for the oldest son than for any other prime-age household member. [35] In India, Bertrand, Mullainathan, Simeon Djankov and Rema Hanna study corruption using the allocation of driver's licenses and find that the illegal obtention of licenses is mostly performed by using private intermediaries to give bribes so that they may not have to pass the driving test. [36] Finally, more recently, Bertrand has been involved in the evaluation of conditional cash transfer programs, e.g. finding that the postponement of transfers to parents until re-enrollment and the incentivization of graduation and tertiary enrollment both increase enrollment rates at the secondary and tertiary level. [37] Another interesting research she did in the field of development economics was the marketing in aid of decision making to the poor. In this paper she studies the aspects of economic decision making on the life of the poor, and how it is influenced by effective marketing.

Other research

Other topics of Bertrand's research include econometric methodology, welfare cultures, advertising, lobbyism, and trickle-down consumption:

Other activities

Awards, honors and grants

Selected bibliography

Related Research Articles

In economics, money illusion, or price illusion, is a cognitive bias where money is thought of in nominal, rather than real terms. In other words, the face value of money is mistaken for its purchasing power at a previous point in time. Viewing purchasing power as measured by the nominal value is false, as modern fiat currencies have no intrinsic value and their real value depends purely on the price level. The term was coined by Irving Fisher in Stabilizing the Dollar. It was popularized by John Maynard Keynes in the early twentieth century, and Irving Fisher wrote an important book on the subject, The Money Illusion, in 1928.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Sendhil Mullainathan</span> American Professor of Computation and Behavioral science

Sendhil Mullainathan is an American professor of economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. He was a professor of Computation and Behavioral Science at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business from 2018-2024. He is the author of Scarcity: Why Having Too Little Means So Much. He was hired with tenure by Harvard in 2004 after having spent six years at MIT.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Field experiment</span> Experiment conducted outside the laboratory

Field experiments are experiments carried out outside of laboratory settings.

Employment discrimination is a form of illegal discrimination in the workplace based on legally protected characteristics. In the U.S., federal anti-discrimination law prohibits discrimination by employers against employees based on age, race, gender, sex, religion, national origin, and physical or mental disability. State and local laws often protect additional characteristics such as marital status, veteran status and caregiver/familial status. Earnings differentials or occupational differentiation—where differences in pay come from differences in qualifications or responsibilities—should not be confused with employment discrimination. Discrimination can be intended and involve disparate treatment of a group or be unintended, yet create disparate impact for a group.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Immigration</span> Movement of people into another country or region to which they are not native

Immigration is the international movement of people to a destination country of which they are not usual residents or where they do not possess nationality in order to settle as permanent residents. Commuters, tourists, and other short-term stays in a destination country do not fall under the definition of immigration or migration; seasonal labour immigration is sometimes included, however.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Fabrizio Zilibotti</span> Italian economist

Fabrizio Zilibotti is an Italian economist. He is the Tuntex Professor of International and Development Economics at Yale University. Zilibotti was previously professor of economics at University College London, the University of Zürich, and at the Institute for International Economic Studies in Stockholm.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Joshua Angrist</span> Israeli–American economist

Joshua David Angrist is an Israeli–American economist and Ford Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Angrist, together with Guido Imbens, was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 2021 "for their methodological contributions to the analysis of causal relationships".

Lawrence Francis Katz is the Elisabeth Allison Professor of Economics at Harvard University and a Research Associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab</span> Global research center working to reduce poverty

The Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab (J-PAL) is a global research center based at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology aimed to reducing poverty by ensuring that policy is informed by rigorous, scientific evidence. J-PAL funds, provides technical support to, and disseminates the results of randomized controlled trials evaluating the efficacy of social interventions in health, education, agriculture, and a range of other fields. As of 2020, the J-PAL network consisted of 500 researchers and 400 staff, and the organization's programs had impacted over 400 million people globally. The organization has regional offices in seven countries around the world, and is headquartered near the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Race is one of the correlates of crime receiving attention in academic studies, government surveys, media coverage, and public concern. Research has found that social status, poverty, and childhood exposure to violent behavior are causes of the racial disparities in crime. Research conducted in Europe and the United States on the matter has been widely published, particularly in relation to discrimination by criminal justice systems.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Eldar Shafir</span>

Eldar Shafir is an American behavioral scientist, and the co-author of Scarcity: Why Having Too Little Means So Much. He is the Class of 1987 Professor in Behavioral Science and Public Policy; Professor of Psychology and Public Affairs at Princeton University Department of Psychology and the Princeton School of Public and International Affairs, and Inaugural Director of Princeton’s Kahneman-Treisman Center for Behavioral Science and Public Policy.

Alan Manning is a British economist and professor of economics at the London School of Economics.

Jeffrey Richard Kling is the research director at the Congressional Budget Office, and was previously the associate director for economic analysis. Kling is also a faculty research fellow at the National Bureau of Economic Research and a senior investigator for the long-term evaluation of the Moving to Opportunity randomized housing mobility experiment.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Robin Burgess</span> British economist

Robin Burgess is a British economist who is Professor of Economics, Co-founder and Director of the International Growth Centre, as well as Co-Founder and Director of the Economics of Energy and the Environment (EEE) program at the London School of Economics and Political Science.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economics of digitization</span>

The economics of digitization is the field of economics that studies how digitization, digitalisation and digital transformation affects markets and how digital data can be used to study economics. Digitization is the process by which technology lowers the costs of storing, sharing, and analyzing data. This has changed how consumers behave, how industrial activity is organized, and how governments operate. The economics of digitization exists as a distinct field of economics for three reasons: it studies a world that is digital, exponential and combinatorial. First, new economic models are needed because digital goods have very low or even zero marginal costs unlike most traditional goods, thus many traditional assumptions no longer hold in a digitized world. Second, the rate of improvement of computers, networks and other engines of digitization, is exponential, as reflected by Moore's Law. Third, digital goods can easily be combined and recombined, increasing their value not only via networks and platforms, but also novel combinations. Each of these effects is important individually, but together they have synergies and constitute a distinct economic landscape.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">David Autor</span> American economist

David H. Autor is an American economist, public policy scholar, and professor of economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), where he also acts as co-director of the School Effectiveness and Inequality Initiative. Although Autor has contributed to a variety of fields in economics his research generally focuses on topics from labor economics.

A type of study used in economics, sociology, political science, and psychology, an audit study is one in which trained employees of the researcher ("auditors") are matched on all characteristics except the one being tested for discrimination. These auditors then apply for a service, be it a job, financial advice regarding their stock portfolio, housing, or a credit card, to test for discrimination.

Antoinette Schoar is a German-American economist, currently the Stewart C. Myers-Horn Family Professor of Finance and Entrepreneurship at the MIT Sloan School of Management.

David Thesmar is a French economist who works as Franco Modigliani Professor Financial Economics at the MIT Sloan School of Management. His research interests include corporate finance, financial intermediation, entrepreneurship and behavioural economics. In 2007, he was awarded the Prize of the Best Young Economist of France.

Jessica Pan is a Singaporean economist currently serving as professor of economics at the National University of Singapore. Her research focuses on applied topics in labor economics, especially related to gender, migration, discrimination, and the returns of education. In 2020, she was elected a Fellow of the Econometric Society.

References

  1. An Interview with Marianne Bertrand, 2004 Elaine Bennett Research Award Winner
  2. CSWEP: Elaine Bennett Research Prize
  3. Marianne Bertrand ranks among the top 1% of labour economists registered on IDEAS/RePEc. Retrieved April 20, 2018.
  4. "CSWEP: Elaine Bennett Research Prize". American Economic Association . Retrieved October 4, 2023.
  5. "Society of Labor Economists (2012). Award of Sherwin Rosen Prize to Marianne Bertrand. Retrieved April 20, 2018". Archived from the original on September 9, 2015. Retrieved April 20, 2018.
  6. "Marianne Bertrand". The Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab (J-PAL). Retrieved October 4, 2023.
  7. "Curriculum vitae of Marianne Bertrand" (PDF). Booth School of Business . Archived from the original (PDF) on April 21, 2018. Retrieved April 20, 2018.
  8. Bertrand, Marianne. "Google Scholar" . Retrieved September 20, 2024.
  9. Top 10% Authors. Retrieved November 4, 2018.
  10. Top 10% female economists. Retrieved November 4, 2018.
  11. Bertrand, Marianne (August 2024). "Top 10% Authors, as of August 2024". IDEAS/Repec. Retrieved September 20, 2024.
  12. Bertrand, Marianne; Mullainathan, Sendhil (1999). "Is there Discretion in Wage Setting? A Test Using Takeover Legislation". The RAND Journal of Economics. 30 (3): 535–554. doi:10.2307/2556062. hdl: 1721.1/63744 . JSTOR   2556062. S2CID   18973218.
  13. Bertrand, Marianne; Mullainathan, Sendhil (2004). "Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal? A Field Experiment on Labor Market Discrimination". American Economic Review. 94 (4): 991–1013. doi:10.1257/0002828042002561. hdl: 1721.1/63261 .
  14. Bertrand, Marianne; Chugh, Dolly; Mullainathan, Sendhil (2005). "Implicit Discrimination". American Economic Review. 95 (2): 94–98. doi:10.1257/000282805774670365.
  15. Abrams, David S.; Bertrand, Marianne; Mullainathan, Sendhil (2012). "Do Judges Vary in Their Treatment of Race?". The Journal of Legal Studies. 41 (2): 347–383. doi:10.1086/666006. S2CID   2338687.
  16. Bertrand, M.; Kramarz, F. (2002). "Does Entry Regulation Hinder Job Creation? Evidence from the French Retail Industry". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117 (4): 1369–1413. doi:10.1162/003355302320935052. hdl: 10419/20031 . S2CID   73615167.
  17. Bertrand, Marianne (2004). "From the Invisible Handshake to the Invisible Hand? How Import Competition Changes the Employment Relationship". Journal of Labor Economics. 22 (4): 723–765. doi:10.1086/423153. S2CID   46585049.
  18. Bertrand, Marianne; Hallock, Kevin F. (2001). "The Gender Gap in Top Corporate Jobs". ILR Review. 55: 3–21. doi:10.1177/001979390105500101. hdl: 1813/76173 . S2CID   21081800.
  19. Bertrand, Marianne; Goldin, Claudia; Katz, Lawrence F. (2010). "Dynamics of the Gender Gap for Young Professionals in the Financial and Corporate Sectors". American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 2 (3): 228–255. doi:10.1257/app.2.3.228. S2CID   3644531.
  20. Bertrand, M. (2011). "New perspectives on gender". In Card, D.; Ashenfelter, O. (eds.). Handbook of Labor Economics. Vol. 4. Amsterdam: Elsevier. pp. 1543–1590.
  21. Bertrand, Marianne; Kamenica, Emir; Pan, Jessica (2015). "Gender Identity and Relative Income within Households". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 130 (2): 571–614. doi:10.1093/qje/qjv001.
  22. Bertrand, Marianne; Pan, Jessica (2013). "The Trouble with Boys: Social Influences and the Gender Gap in Disruptive Behavior". American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 5: 32–64. doi:10.1257/app.5.1.32. S2CID   55049353.
  23. "Marianne Bertrand". The University of Chicago Booth School of Business. Retrieved 2019-04-23.
  24. Bertrand, Marianne; Mullainathan, Sendhil (2000). "Agents with and Without Principals". American Economic Review. 90 (2): 203–208. doi:10.1257/aer.90.2.203.
  25. Bertrand, M.; Mullainathan, S. (2001). "Are CEOs Rewarded for Luck? The Ones Without Principals Are". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 116 (3): 901–932. doi:10.1162/00335530152466269.
  26. Bertrand, Marianne; Mullainathan, Sendhil (2003). "Enjoying the Quiet Life? Corporate Governance and Managerial Preferences". Journal of Political Economy. 111 (5): 1043–1075. doi:10.1086/376950. S2CID   4693227.
  27. Bertrand, M.; Schoar, A. (2003). "Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 118 (4): 1169–1208. doi:10.1162/003355303322552775. hdl: 1721.1/1824 .
  28. Bertrand, Marianne; Schoar, Antoinette; Thesmar, David (2007). "Banking Deregulation and Industry Structure: Evidence from the French Banking Reforms of 1985". The Journal of Finance. 62 (2): 597–628. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01218.x . S2CID   14677170.
  29. Bertrand, Marianne; Morse, Adair (2011). "Information Disclosure, Cognitive Biases, and Payday Borrowing". The Journal of Finance. 66 (6): 1865–1893. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.2011.01698.x.
  30. Bertrand, Marianne; Schoar, Antoinette (2006). "The Role of Family in Family Firms". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 20 (2): 73–96. doi: 10.1257/jep.20.2.73 .
  31. Bertrand, Marianne; Johnson, Simon; Samphantharak, Krislert; Schoar, Antoinette (2008). "Mixing family with business: A study of Thai business groups and the families behind them". Journal of Financial Economics. 88 (3): 466–498. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2008.04.002.
  32. Bertrand, M.; Mehta, P.; Mullainathan, S. (2002). "Ferreting out Tunneling: An Application to Indian Business Groups". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117: 121–148. doi:10.1162/003355302753399463. hdl: 1721.1/63630 .
  33. Bertrand, Marianne; Mullainathan, Sendhil; Shafir, Eldar (2004). "A Behavioral-Economics View of Poverty". American Economic Review. 94 (2): 419–423. doi:10.1257/0002828041302019. S2CID   2865749.
  34. Bertrand, Marianne; Mullainathan, Sendhil; Shafir, Eldar (2006). "Behavioral Economics and Marketing in Aid of Decision Making among the Poor". Journal of Public Policy & Marketing. 25: 8–23. doi:10.1509/jppm.25.1.8. S2CID   14451745.
  35. Bertrand, M. (2003). "Public Policy and Extended Families: Evidence from Pensions in South Africa". The World Bank Economic Review. 17: 27–50. doi:10.1093/wber/lhg014. hdl: 10986/17171 .
  36. Bertrand, M.; Djankov, S.; Hanna, R.; Mullainathan, S. (2007). "Obtaining a Driver's License in India: An Experimental Approach to Studying Corruption". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 122 (4): 1639–1676. doi:10.1162/qjec.2007.122.4.1639.
  37. Barrera-Osorio, Felipe; Bertrand, Marianne; Linden, Leigh L.; Perez-Calle, Francisco (2011). "Improving the Design of Conditional Transfer Programs: Evidence from a Randomized Education Experiment in Colombia". American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 3 (2): 167–195. doi:10.1257/app.3.2.167. S2CID   53589026.
  38. Bertrand, Marianne; Mullainathan, Sendhil (2001). "Do People Mean What They Say? Implications for Subjective Survey Data". American Economic Review. 91 (2): 67–72. doi:10.1257/aer.91.2.67. hdl: 1721.1/63464 .
  39. Bertrand, M.; Duflo, E.; Mullainathan, S. (2004). "How Much Should We Trust Differences-In-Differences Estimates?". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 119: 249–275. doi:10.1162/003355304772839588. hdl: 1721.1/63690 .
  40. Bertrand, Marianne; Luttmer, Erzo F. P.; Mullainathan, Sendhil (2000). "Network Effects and Welfare Cultures". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 115 (3): 1019–1055. doi:10.1162/003355300554971. hdl: 1721.1/63969 .
  41. Bertrand, Marianne; Karlan, Dean; Mullainathan, Sendhil; Shafir, Eldar; Zinman, Jonathan (2010). "What's Advertising Content Worth? Evidence from a Consumer Credit Marketing Field Experiment*". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 125: 263–305. doi:10.1162/qjec.2010.125.1.263. S2CID   3231264.
  42. Bertrand, Marianne; Bombardini, Matilde; Trebbi, Francesco (2014). "Is It Whom You Know or What You Know? An Empirical Assessment of the Lobbying Process". American Economic Review. 104 (12): 3885–3920. doi:10.1257/aer.104.12.3885.
  43. Bertrand, Marianne; Morse, Adair (2016). "Trickle-Down Consumption". Review of Economics and Statistics. 98 (5): 863–879. doi:10.1162/REST_a_00613. S2CID   18066770.
  44. "Research". faculty.chicagobooth.edu. Retrieved 2023-10-04.
  45. BSE Board appoints 5 new Scientific Council members Barcelona School of Economics, press release of November 2022.
  46. "Economist with focus on inequality receives new Swedish prize in economics and management".
  47. "Marianne Bertrand: Personal Website at Chicago Booth".
  48. "Awards". American Academy of Sciences & Letters. Retrieved 2024-10-27.