United States v. Westinghouse Electric Co.

Last updated
United States v. Westinghouse Electric Co.
Seal of the United States Courts, Ninth Judicial Circuit.svg
Court United States Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit
Full case nameUnited States of America, Plaintiff-Appellant, v. Westinghouse Electric Corporation, Mitsubishi Electric Corporation, and Mitsubishi Heavy Industries, Ltd., Defendants-Appellees.
Mitsubishi Electric Corporation, and Mitsubishi Heavy Industries, Ltd., Defendants-Cross-Appellants, v. United States of America, Plaintiff-Cross-Appellee
ArguedDecember 8, 1980
DecidedJune 18, 1981
Citation(s)648 F.2d 642
Case history
Prior history471 F. Supp. 532 (N.D. Cal. 1978)
Court membership
Judge(s) sitting Ben C. Duniway, Irving Loeb Goldberg, [1] William Canby
Case opinions
MajorityDuniway, joined by a unanimous panel

United States v. Westinghouse Electric Corp., [2] 648 F.2d 642 (9th Cir. 1981), is a patent-antitrust case in which the United States unsuccessfully tried to persuade the court that a patent and technology licensing agreement between major competitors in the highly concentrated heavy electrical equipment market—Westinghouse, Mitsubishi Electric (Melco) and Mitsubishi Heavy Industries (MHI)—which had the effect of territorially dividing world markets, violated § 1 of the Sherman Act. [3] The Government had two principal theories of the case: (1) the arrangement is in unreasonable restraint of trade because its effect is to lessen competition substantially by precluding the Japanese defendant companies from bidding against Westinghouse on equipment procurements in the United States, when they are ready, willing, and able to do so; and (2) the arrangement is an agreement—explicit or tacit—to divide markets, which is illegal per se under § 1. [4] Neither theory prevailed.

Contents

Background

General Electric (not a party to this action) and Westinghouse are the two leading U.S. manufacturers and sellers of heavy electrical equipment such as power transformers, power circuit breakers, hydroelectric generators, and gas and steam turbines. Melco and MHI are the leading Japanese manufacturers and sellers of such equipment. The relationship between Westinghouse and the two Mitsubishi defendants and their predecessors extends back to the early part of the 20th century. Prior to World War II they were parties to contracts (for example, a 1923 contract, which, the district court said, "apparently divided world markets between Westinghouse and the predecessors of the Mitsubishi defendants') under which Westinghouse supplied them technical and manufacturing information and received royalties on the sale of their products. These agreements permitted the predecessors of the Mitsubishi defendants to sell the products only in Japan and China. The arrangement was interrupted by World War II.

After the War, Westinghouse entered into the first of several technical assistance agreements with Melco in 1951 and with a predecessor of MHI in 1952. These agreements have continued since that time; they licensed Melco and MHI under Westinghouse's heavy electrical equipment patents to make and sell throughout the world except Canada and the United States, and provided for Westinghouse to furnish Melco and MHI with technical information to make the products. The agreements reciprocally authorized Westinghouse to make and sell, except in Japan, products incorporating patented technology and know-how that Melco and MHI transferred to Westinghouse. [5] The Government sued Westinghouse, Melco, and MHI in the Northern District of California (San Francisco) for combining and conspiring to restrain trade and commerce in heavy electrical equipment.

The Government relied on evidence which "conclusively establish[ed] that Melco and MHI each refrained from selling products falling within the Licensing and Technology Agreements in the United States and Canada without first obtaining Westinghouse approval." The evidence was mainly sets of correspondence and other documents relating to a number of bidding "incidents," in each of which a Japanese defendants wrote to Westinghouse requesting to bid on a particular hydroelectric project or other project using heavy electrical equipment, and then Westinghouse granted the request if it was not interested in itself bidding or denied the request otherwise. [6]

For example, the government cited the period from January 1966 to March 1967 in which Mitsubishi Electric received a number of specific bid inquiries for the sale of electrical equipment to the United States, including projects for the Sacramento Municipal Utility District, the California Department of Water Resources, the Turlock & Modesto Irrigation District (California), and the Bureau of Reclamation, United States Department of the Interior. In each instance Westinghouse, after inquiry from Mitsubishi Electric, refused to allow Mitsubishi Electric to bid on the projects, and it did not do so. [7]

The district court concluded, however, that this merely showed the Japanese defendants' desire to avoid committing patent infringement. The court also said that the parties' agreements "provide a strong inference that patents extend to all licensed products involved in this suit." Thus, the court said, "the Government's own evidence thus raises competing inferences of a legitimate 'patent motivation,' on the one hand, and an illegal agreement, on the other, to explain defendants' conduct," and the Government failed to persuade the court that the motivation was a desire to divide territories rather than to respect patent rights. [6]

The Government also offered a number of documents in which permission to bid in the United States or Canada was denied without mention of patents. The court refused to infer that this indicated an illegal agreement to divide markets. It said:

Contrary to the Government's assertions, the precise language used by the defendants in their day-to-day dealings is not indicative of an illegal arrangement simply because the word "patent" was not used. It is hardly strange or incriminating for the parties in dealings among themselves or with strangers to say that the agreement "prohibits sale in the United States," even though a more precise statement would be, for example, that "since our agreement does not give patent licenses for sales in the United States any such sales are, in effect, prohibited because they could result in patent infringement litigation." This is particularly true of those employees and independent marketing agents whose obvious interest is in whether, as opposed to why, a product can or cannot be sold. [8]

The district court (Judge Stanley Weigel) held that the legal significance of the repeated case–by–case requests for approval to bid "depends on the state of mind of Melco and MHI in seeking Westinghouse approval." The court refused to infer the existence of an illegal agreement not to compete in the United States. It agreed with the defendants that Melco and MHI did not refrain from competing in the United States on the basis of an illegal agreement with Westinghouse but rather out of fear of infringing Westinghouse patents. The court dismissed the contention that the grant of a patent license outside the United States coupled with case–by–case and customer–by–customer approvals or denials of bid permission violated § 1 of the Sherman Act. The court approved instead the argument that "a patentee's right to shut off all competition must necessarily include the lesser right to restrict the exercise of the granted privilege so long as the patentee does not attach a condition that enlarges his monopoly beyond that given by the patent statute and the patent itself." [9] The court dismissed the case.

Ruling of Ninth Circuit

The Government appealed the dismissal judgment to the Ninth Circuit, which affirmed the judgment of no antitrust violation.

The court described the Government's principal theory in these terms"

The United States market for the electrical products covered by the agreements is heavily concentrated. Although they are two of the largest manufacturers of electrical products outside the United States, MHI and MELCO do not compete in this market. Their entrance into the United States market would substantially increase the amount of competition in that market. By 1965 MELCO and MHI wished to sell in the United States and had the technical ability to design around Westinghouse's many patents. Their failure to do so, the government contends, is a direct result of the Technical Assistance Agreements. Because MELCO and MHI are licensed by the Agreements under Westinghouse's foreign patents, and because they have had such licenses for a long period of time, they have become so committed to Westinghouse technology as to be economically incapable of developing new products that might compete in the United States without infringing upon Westinghouse's United States patents. Without licenses under Westinghouse's United States patents, MELCO and MHI are effectively barred from the United States market by dint of the patent laws and the heavy investment in Westinghouse technology that the Technical Assistance Agreements induced them to make. [10]

The Ninth Circuit considered this theory "novel and laced with paradox":

By the act of helping MELCO and MHI to prosper and to grow into large corporations in its own image, Westinghouse is said to have insulated its home market from their competition in violation of the antitrust laws. The government urges that although the Agreements may not have resulted in an unreasonable restraint of trade when first signed in 1951 and 1952, at some point in 1965, when MELCO and MHI became capable of competing in the United States and capable of designing around Westinghouse's patents but for their investment in Westinghouse technology, the Agreements came to violate the antitrust laws. Accordingly, the government asked the district court to order an end to the Agreements and to require Westinghouse to license MELCO and MHI under its United States patents. [11]

The Government's main appeal argument was "that Mitsubishi has become so wedded to Westinghouse technology, because of the Agreements, as to be unable to compete in the United States market," The court responded:

In advancing its theory, however, the government argues that an antitrust violation may be found where a patent holder does precisely that which the patent laws authorize. Westinghouse has done no more than to license some of its patents and refuse to license others. . . , The right to license that patent, exclusively or otherwise, or to refuse to license at all, is "the untrammeled right" of the patentee. In short, in granting MELCO and MHI some licenses but not others, Westinghouse did no more than employ means "normally and reasonably adapted to secure pecuniary reward for the [patent] monopoly." [12]

By the same token, the Government's theory that:

[B]ecause Westinghouse has, in effect, burdened Mitsubishi with its foreign patent licenses, thus tying it to Westinghouse technology, Westinghouse should now be required to license its United States patents to Mitsubishi, so that Mitsubishi can compete in the United States . . . flies in the face of the rule that a holder of United States patents has a right to refuse to license them. [13]

"The antitrust laws do not grant the government a roving commission to reform the economy at will," the court added. Just because a patentee has granted a potential competitor some licenses does not mean that the patentee must grant additional licenses. Furthermore, the theory that a license lawful in its exception could become unlawful at a later time when the licensee has "flourished under the agreement" is unacceptable because it would "seriously undermine" the patent system. Thus, "even if it is true that MHI and MELCO would have entered the United States electrical equipment market by designing new products but for their existing success with Westinghouse technology, there is no basis for the theory in law." [13]

The Ninth Circuit also rejected the theory that the case-by-case grants and denials of permissions to bid showed an agreement to divide territories. The Government argued that the district court's determination that Melco and MHI did not refrain from bidding without permission on the basis of an illegal agreement with Westinghouse but rather out of fear of infringing Westinghouse patents was immaterial:

The Government now argues that the court erred in focusing on motivation: If the effect of the Agreements and of the requests for and denials or grants of approval was to unreasonably limit competition in the United States, then the Agreements violate the antitrust laws regardless of whether the motivation of the parties is to divide the market or to avoid patent infringement. [14]

The court said that the Government must prove bad intent in order to prevail, and it did not do so. "The desire of Mitsubishi to avoid infringing upon Westinghouse's many patents—perhaps even as to products only arguably covered by Westinghouse's patents—undoubtedly has an effect on competition, but this is an effect which results from the monopoly granted by the patent laws and does not establish an antitrust violation by the companies in this case." [14]

The Government did not seek to petition the Supreme Court for certiorari in this case, its decision reflecting a change of prosecutorial policy with a change of Administration. [15]

Commentary

● Several months after the Westinghouse–Mitsubishi case was filed the Wall Street Journal quoted the President of Magnavox Corp. as saying: "If the Justice Department's effort is successful, we are all in jeopardy. The consequences would be an undisciplined international scramble for markets." The Journal also quoted the U.S. Department of Commerce as disapproving of the case because its success would "cut domestic profits and jobs and adversely affect our balance of payments." [16]

● Thomas Vakerics, in Antitrust Basics, comments that the effect of Westinghouse's arrangement was equivalent to a horizontal allocation of territories:

By refusing to license Mitsubishi under its United States patents, Westinghouse was able to exclude Mitsubishi from selling the patented products in the United States. Thus there apparently were no territorial restrictions in the license agreements and no express agreement between the parties that transmit would not sell the patented products in the United States. By licensing transmit only under its foreign patents, however, Westinghouse was able to keep Mitsubishi out of the United States market and the effect of the arrangement was precisely the same as if territorial allocations had been expressly contained in the license. [17]

Richard H. Stern, at that time chief of the Justice Department patent–antitrust unit, in a 1970 article in IDEA, [18] described the legal theory of the Westinghouse–Mitsubishi case, which had then recently been filed, without explicitly mentioning it by name. He began by describing the various ways that one could effectuate a division of domestic and foreign exploitation rights for patented technology:

  1. a license coupled with an express agreement against importation into the United States (a so-called negative covenant);
  2. a license on condition that the licensee not export to the United States; and
  3. most often, a license of foreign patents without a corresponding license of domestic counterpart patents.

He argued that the distinction among the three formats is without "special significance" because "niceties in wording will not save what is an otherwise unlawful scheme," [19] at least in domestic market allocation schemes. He then argues that the same principle applies in international licensing. He maintains that the "definitional problem of characterizing a territory provision in a license as a 'restriction' or not" should be subordinated to the more important "problem of determining whether the alleged restriction is in fact an undue one." [20]

He then turns to the per se rule against allocation of territories of the Supreme Court's cartel cases, but suggests caution in applying it to international patent licensing. He stated:

Carried to its ultimate logical conclusion, this principle against allocation of markets might seem to outlaw any licensing agreement by which the owner of any domestic and foreign patent, whether of major or minor technological significance, granted a license under only one of the two patents. Nevertheless, to take the principle so broadly, as a matter of principle and without a more detailed economic analysis, would seem . . . probably to carry the rule farther than we should go. The problem should not be viewed as one of mere characterization (viz., should this provision be deemed a division-of markets agreement?) but rather as one of whether the economic effect is anticompetitive in the manner a division of markets injures competition. [21]

He then addresses the distinction that, unlike domestic market allocations and international nonpatent allocations, international patent licensing allocations rely on sovereign grants compartmentalized along national boundary lines, thus implicating "discrete legal rights." He explained that this is a matter to be considered—"a proper accommodation of patent and antitrust policies should take this distinction into account"—but it is not necessarily determinative: "The question then becomes one of the degree to which this distinction should be considered to make a legal difference, for again the effect, and not the label, should be determinative of the outcome. [21]

Stern then describes a continuum of fact patterns. At one end is a division of rights under one U.S. patent and a foreign counterpart of it, perhaps commercially of little importance. This arrangement is not of antitrust concern. The pattern at the other end of the continuum involves a contract between two major firms in a concentrated industry; the firms are potential competitors in each other's markets; the product and dollar volume is large; many different products and product lines are involved; the arrangement persists for a long time; the factors, taken together, suggest that incentives exist for the foreign partner to enter the U.S. market with technology derived otherwise and without a restriction against export to this country. [22]

The easy antitrust cases are at the two ends of the continuum, he says, and the more difficult cases are in the middle. Stern suggests that this calls for the type of analysis the Supreme Court required in United States v. Columbia Steel Co. , [23] two decades earlier, "which is one of more or less, rather than one of absolutes." He concedes that "such an analysis is not wholly satisfactory for predicting the outcome of litigation," but it indicates that to avoid problems one should avoid unnecessarily titling the balance of factors to the unfavorable end of the continuum in drafting licenses. One should not put restrictions unneeded for business reasons into licenses just "as a matter of principle or habit." [24] He maintains that it is not necessary to try to find out how close to the edge of a precipice it is possible to walk without falling over, and asserts that many businessmen "are able to conduct their affairs satisfactorily without trying to see how close to the Plimsoll Line it is possible to load the ship"—and at the same time do so "without any undue damage to legitimate business expectations." [25]

● Howard Forman, in a 1971 article in IDEA, took issue with the positions being advanced at the Justice Department, and stated a view closer to that which the court of appeals took a decade later in the appeal of the Westinghouse–Mitsubishi judgment. [26] Forman insisted that it is "not plausible to apply antitrust standards established for domestic purposes to situations involving patents granted and maintained under the laws of foreign countries where the standards may be totally different." [27] He cautioned flexibility in applying the U.S. antitrust laws "to the end that the efficiency of mass production is not destroyed, orderly marketing conditions are insured, and economic dislocations of great industries are avoided." He warned that otherwise over-enforcement of antitrust might lead to "the possibility of killing the economic goose that lays the golden eggs of productivity and commerce." [28]

Forman begins by challenging the equation of a failure to grant a foreign licensee a license to the U.S. counterpart patent, on the one hand, with a territorial limitation or territorial restriction, on the other hand. Forman insists that a :failure" is not an affirmative act, the implication being that the antitrust laws proscribe only affirmative or positive actions, not inactions or failures to act. [29]

Forman then objects to what he perceives as a governmental approach to the antitrust legality of international licensing base exclusively on the economic effect in the United States. He posits a hypothetical case in which A has patents in the United States, France, and Italy, and wants to license B in France and Italy, but not in the United States. Hypothetically, the French and Italian governments are anxious to have the patents worked in their countries, but the U.S. Department of Justice may object. Forman argues:

It would seem that the French and Italian governments have a prevailing legal right; and company A has a legal privilege or duty to exercise its foreign patents, as permitted or required under the laws of the countries which granted them, without concern over the possible economic effects which such exercise, sans the right in the foreign licensees to practice the invention in the U.S., may have in the U.S. [30]

Forman chides Stern and the Justice Department for "somewhat shallowly" subordinating the rights of foreign sovereigns to antitrust policies of the United States directed to protecting the U.S. economy and disregarding the wishes of U.S. patent owners in how most profitably to exploit their technology creations. What if the foreign country has a "compulsory working requirement," Forman asks, and the penalty for not working a patent is its forfeiture? If the U.S. company is in no position to work the patent in a foreign country, the logical thing to do is license to a foreign company. If that results in the U.S. antitrust authorities forcing him to grant the foreign company a license also on the U.S. patent, "this would be tantamount to establishing a system of compulsory patent licensing in the United States," which only Congress has the authority to do. Forman then accuses the Department of Justice of "encroaching on the prerogatives of the Congress" if it persists in this "misapplication of our antitrust laws." [31]

● Douglas Rosenthal, a former Justice Department official, commented on the Ninth Circuit's opinion affirming the dismissal of the government's case. He stated that the court's opinion represented only "one possible reading of the trial record, which can be read to reach a different result." In his view:

A review of the record reveals that serious anticompetitive problems existed with the Westinghouse-Mitsubishi licenses. At the time of the trial, the agreements between the two multi-billion-dollar international enterprises in the highly concentrated international electrical equipment industry were over fifty years old. They covered know-how as well as patent transfers. The licenses covered virtually all of their electrical product lines (hundreds of products), and prevented each company from competing in the other's home market. The license also did not detail the specific patents held by each company that would have ostensibly blocked entry into the market of the other country. The combination of such a broad cross-license, in which the property is not clearly described, with territorial restrictions, for such an extended period, would suggest that much of the licenses' technology, whether patent or know-how, is of little value and that the purpose and effect of the licenses is to restrict potential competition rather than to share technology. [32]

He therefore asked the question whether one should conclude that the arrangement, while lawful in its postwar inception when Mitsubishi was not a substantial competitive factor in the industry, arguably lost its legality once the licensee, Mitsubishi, became fully competitive with the licensor, Westinghouse, sometime in the 1960s. [33]

● In an earlier article, Rosenthal and two other former State Department and Justice Department officials, commented on the trial court's decision in the case. [34] They perceive "an impasse as to what types of technology-sharing arrangements between large firms in concentrated markets should be and are illegal," marked by several contradictory legal theories. [35] "The first, and most dubious," they say, is that of Judge Weigel in the Westinghouse-Mitsubishi case. His theory, they explain is:

His decision was based on two considerations: (1) it is necessary to prove anticompetitive intent to render such an agreement illegal, regardless of the anticompetitive effect, and (2) no such intent is shown here because the most plausible explanation for the failure of Mitsubishi to sell in the United States in competition with Westinghouse is fear of infringing on Westinghouse patents. [36]

This theory, they assert, "flatly contradicts the Supreme Court decision in National Society of Professional Engineers v. United States , which held that the legality of agreements must be tested against their effect on competition." In addition, they argue, it was error to require the government to bear the burden to "introduce...specific evidence showing that there were Westinghouse patents actually blocking Mitsubishi sales," because under prior precedent it is the burden of the patentee to show patent coverage. [37]

They describe an alternative theory, proposed on appeal:

A major manufacturer in a highly concentrated market may not repeatedly renew broad, multiproduct, multipatent license agreements that have the effect of disabling major potential competitors from providing badly needed additional competition in the United States. [38]

They suggest that although long–term international patent licensing does promote some efficient dissemination of technology, "the disincentives to independent research in concentrated industries, stemming from dependence, on a licensee effectively eliminated from the competitive market for perhaps two or three decades" may well outweigh the public benefits of such collaboration. [39] "The essential problem," they say, is determining whether or how long it would take before "a licensee could become a competitor of the licensor without the benefit of the license." But there is no objective or precise way to establish this. Therefore, they propose that:

[T]he most effective approach for exercising greater control over excessive concentration by technology licensing would be to shift the burden of proof to the licensing parties where the territorial restraint exceeds a period of, say, fifteen years, and the parties are large, well-financed, technologically sophisticated, and operating in noncompetitive industries with significant barriers to entry. [40]

Related Research Articles

Patent infringement is the commission of a prohibited act with respect to a patented invention without permission from the patent holder. Permission may typically be granted in the form of a license. The definition of patent infringement may vary by jurisdiction, but it typically includes using or selling the patented invention. In many countries, a use is required to be commercial to constitute patent infringement.

In United States patent law, patent misuse is a patent holder's use of a patent to restrain trade beyond enforcing the exclusive rights that a lawfully obtained patent provides. If a court finds that a patent holder committed patent misuse, the court may rule that the patent holder has lost the right to enforce the patent. Patent misuse that restrains economic competition substantially can also violate United States antitrust law.

Quanta Computer, Inc. v. LG Electronics, Inc., 553 U.S. 617 (2008), is a decision of the United States Supreme Court in which the Court reaffirmed the validity of the patent exhaustion doctrine, and in doing so made uncertain the continuing precedential value of a line of decisions in the Federal Circuit that had sought to limit Supreme Court exhaustion doctrine decisions to their facts and to require a so-called "rule of reason" analysis of all post-sale restrictions other than tie-ins and price fixes. In the course of restating the patent exhaustion doctrine, the Court held that the exhaustion doctrine is triggered by, among other things, an authorized sale of a component when the only reasonable and intended use of the component is to practice the patent and the component substantially embodies the patented invention by embodying its essential features. The Court also overturned, in passing, the part of decision below that held that the exhaustion doctrine was limited to product claims and did not apply to method claims.

United States v. General Electric Co., 272 U.S. 476 (1926), is a decision of the United States Supreme Court holding that a patentee who has granted a single license to a competitor to manufacture the patented product may lawfully fix the price at which the licensee may sell the product.

A post-sale restraint, also termed a post-sale restriction, as those terms are used in United States patent law and antitrust law, is a limitation that operates after a sale of goods to a purchaser has occurred and purports to restrain, restrict, or limit the scope of the buyer's freedom to utilize, resell, or otherwise dispose of or take action regarding the sold goods. Such restraints have also been termed "equitable servitudes on chattels".

Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992), is a 1992 Supreme Court decision in which the Court held that even though an equipment manufacturer lacked significant market power in the primary market for its equipment—copier-duplicators and other imaging equipment—nonetheless, it could have sufficient market power in the secondary aftermarket for repair parts to be liable under the antitrust laws for its exclusionary conduct in the aftermarket. The reason was that it was possible that, once customers were committed to the particular brand by having purchased a unit, they were "locked in" and no longer had any realistic alternative to turn to for repair parts.

FTC v. Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. 136 (2013), was a United States Supreme Court decision in which the Court held that the FTC could make an antitrust challenge under the rule of reason against a so-called pay-for-delay agreement, also referred to as a reverse payment patent settlement. Such an agreement is one in which a drug patentee pays another company, ordinarily a generic drug manufacturer, to stay out of the market, thus avoiding generic competition and a challenge to patent validity. The FTC sought to establish a rule that such agreements were presumptively illegal, but the Court ruled only that the FTC could bring a case under more general antitrust principles permitting a defendant to assert justifications for its actions under the rule of reason.

Morton Salt Co. v. G.S. Suppiger Co., 314 U.S. 488 (1942), is a patent misuse decision of the United States Supreme Court. It was the first case in which the Court expressly labeled as "misuse" the Motion Picture Patent/Carbice tie-in defense to a charge of patent infringement and created the present blanket remedy in infringement cases of unenforceability of the misused patent. The decision re-emphasized that misuse can be found without finding an antitrust violation.

Kimble v. Marvel Entertainment, LLC, 576 U.S. 446 (2015), is a significant decision of the United States Supreme Court for several reasons. One is that the Court turned back a considerable amount of academic criticism of both the patent misuse doctrine as developed by the Supreme Court and the particular legal principle at issue in the case. Another is that the Court firmly rejected efforts to assimilate the patent misuse doctrine to antitrust law and explained in some detail the different policies at work in the two bodies of law. Finally, the majority and dissenting opinions informatively articulate two opposing views of the proper role of the doctrine of stare decisis in US law.

Brulotte v. Thys Co., 379 U.S. 29 (1964), was a Supreme Court of the United States decision holding that a contract calling for payment of patent royalties after the expiration of the licensed patent was misuse of the patent right and unenforceable under the Supremacy Clause, state contract law notwithstanding. The decision was widely subjected to academic criticism but the Supreme Court has rejected that criticism and reaffirmed the Brulotte decision in Kimble v. Marvel Entertainment, LLC.

Ethyl Gasoline Corp. v. United States, 309 U.S. 436 (1940), was a decision of the United States Supreme Court that limited the doctrine of the Court's 1938 decision in General Talking Pictures Corp. v. Western Electric Co. Beginning with the 1926 decision in United States v. General Electric Co., the Supreme Court made a sharp distinction between (i) post-sale restraints that a patentee imposed on purchasers of a patented product and (ii) restrictions (limitations) that a patentee imposed on a licensee to manufacture a patented product: the former being illegal and unenforceable under the exhaustion doctrine while the latter were generally permissible under a lenient "rule of reason." Thus, under the General Talking Pictures doctrine, a patent holder may permissibly license others to manufacture and then sell patented products in only a specified field (market), such as only a particular type of product made under the patent or only a particular category of customer for the patented product. The Ethyl decision held, however, that a patent licensing and distribution program based on both the sale of a patented product and licenses to manufacture a related product was subject to ordinary testing under the antitrust laws, and accordingly was illegal when its effect was to "regiment" an entire industry.

Princo Corp. v. ITC, 616 F.3d 1318 was a 2010 decision of the United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit, that sought to narrow the defense of patent misuse to claims for patent infringement. Princo held that a party asserting the defense of patent misuse, absent a case of so-called per se misuse, must prove both "leveraging" of the patent being enforced against it and a substantial anticompetitive effect outside the legitimate scope of that patent right. In so ruling, the court emphasized that the misuse alleged must involve the patent in suit, not another patent.

The Mercoid casesMercoid Corp. v. Mid-Continent Investment Co., 320 U.S. 661 (1944), and Mercoid Corp. v. Minneapolis-Honeywell Regulator Co., 320 U.S. 680 (1944)—are 1944 patent tie-in misuse and antitrust decisions of the United States Supreme Court. These companion cases are said to have reached the "high-water mark of the patent misuse doctrine." The Court substantially limited the contributory infringement doctrine by holding unlawful tie-ins of "non-staple" unpatented articles that were specially adapted only for use in practicing a patent, and the Court observed: "The result of this decision, together with those which have preceded it, is to limit substantially the doctrine of contributory infringement. What residuum may be left we need not stop to consider." The Court also suggested that an attempt to extend the reach of a patent beyond its claims could or would violate the antitrust laws: "The legality of any attempt to bring unpatented goods within the protection of the patent is measured by the antitrust laws, not by the patent law."

<i>National Lockwasher Co. v. George K. Garrett Co.</i>

National Lockwasher Co. v. George K. Garrett Co., 137 F.2d 255, is one of the earliest or the earliest federal court decision to hold that it is patent misuse for a patentee to require licensees not to use a competitive technology. Such provisions are known as "tie-outs."

United States v. New Wrinkle, Inc., 342 U.S. 371 (1952), is a 1952 Supreme Court decision in which the Court held that a claim of conspiracy to fix uniform minimum prices and to eliminate competition throughout substantially all of the wrinkle finish industry of the United States by means of patent license agreements was, if proved, a violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act. That one of the defendants, a patent-holding company, abstained from manufacturing activities, did not ship goods in commerce, and engaged solely in patent licensing did not insulate its activity from § 1. Making these license contracts for the purpose of regulating distribution and fixing prices of commodities in interstate commerce is subject to the Sherman Act, even though the isolated act of contracting for the licenses occurs within a single state. Patents give no protection from the prohibitions of the Sherman Act when the patent licensing agreements are used to restrain interstate commerce and fix prices of goods shipped in commerce.

United States v. United States Gypsum Co. was a patent–antitrust case in which the United States Supreme Court decided, first, in 1948, that a patent licensing program that fixed prices of many licensees and regimented an entire industry violated the antitrust laws, and then, decided in 1950, after a remand, that appropriate relief in such cases did not extend so far as to permit licensees enjoying a compulsory, reasonable–royalty license to challenge the validity of the licensed patents. The Court also ruled, in obiter dicta, that the United States had standing to challenge the validity of patents when a patentee relied on the patents to justify its fixing prices. It held in this case, however, that the defendants violated the antitrust laws irrespective of whether the patents were valid, which made the validity issue irrelevant.

<i>United States v. Krasnov</i>

United States v. Krasnov, 143 F. Supp. 184, was a 1956 district court patent–antitrust decision that the United States Supreme Court affirmed per curiam without opinion. The district court granted the Government's summary judgment motion because it concluded:

That the defendants in combination controlled the market and had the ability to and did drive competitors from the business of manufacturing knitted fabric slip covers is abundantly clear from the record. That the defendants in combination fixed and maintained prices is likewise crystal clear. That the defendants in combination and cross-licensing created a situation in the industry which, particularly by agreement for joint action respecting the patents, effectively hindered newcomers in the field, is also established beyond peradventure of doubt. That the harassing suits against competitors, previously discussed in some detail, were designed as and were actually only harassing suits is clear from an examination of the correspondence between the parties and the Court feels that such conclusion in inescapable from an objective analysis of the documents. All of these actions taken in concert constitute a clear violation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act and the Government has established to the satisfaction of the Court that the combination and conspiracy above referred to represents an unreasonable restraint of trade and commerce among the several states of the United States in the manufacture and sale of ready-made furniture slip covers, is unlawful, and in violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act. Further, the Government, in the opinion of the Court, has effectively demonstrated that the defendants combined and conspired not only to restrain trade unreasonably but also to monopolize trade and commerce among the several states of the United States in the manufacture and sale of ready-made furniture slip covers, in direct violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act. The Court also feels that by documentary proof the Government has established that the defendants have used patent rights unlawfully in instituting, effectuating and maintaining the aforesaid combination and conspiracy which likewise constitutes a clear violation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act.

United States v. Masonite Corp., 316 U.S. 265 (1942), is a United States Supreme Court decision that limited the scope of the 1926 Supreme Court decision in the General Electric case that had exempted patent licensing agreements from antitrust law's prohibition of price fixing. The Court did so by applying the doctrine of the Court's recent Interstate Circuit hub-and-spoke conspiracy decision.

United States v. Line Material Co., 333 U.S. 287 (1948), is a decision of the United States Supreme Court limiting the doctrine of the 1926 General Electric decision, excusing price fixing in patent license agreements. The Line Material Court held that cross-licenses between two manufacturer competitors, providing for fixing the prices of the licensed products and providing that one of the manufacturers would license other manufacturers under the patents of each manufacturer, subject to similar price fixing, violated Sherman Act § 1. The Court further held that the licensees who, with knowledge of such arrangements, entered into the price-fixing licenses thereby became party to a hub-and-spoke conspiracy in violation of Sherman Act § 1.

Hartford-Empire Co. v. United States, 323 U.S. 386 (1945), was a patent-antitrust case that the Government brought against a cartel in the glass container industry. The cartel, among other things, divided the fields of manufacture of glass containers, first, into blown glass and pressed glass, which was subdivided into: products made under the suction process, milk bottles, and fruit jars. The trial court found the cartel violative of the antitrust laws and the Supreme Court agreed that the market division and related conduct were illegal. The trial court required royalty-free licensing of present patents and reasonable royalty licensing of future patents. A divided Supreme Court reversed the requirement for royalty-free licensing as "confiscatory," but sustained the requirement for reasonable royalty licensing of the patents.

References

The citations in this article are written in Bluebook style. Please see the talk page for more information.

  1. The Honorable Irving L. Goldberg was a Senior United States Circuit Judge for the Fifth Circuit, sitting by designation
  2. 648 F.2d 642 (9th Cir. 1981), affirming United States v. Westinghouse Electric Corp., 471 F. Supp. 532 (N.D. Cal., 1978).
  3. 15 U.S.C. § 1.
  4. The case was said to be "one of the most controversial filed by Assistant Attorney General Richard W. McLaren." See James H. Wallace, Multinational Patent And Know-How Arrangements, 39 Antitrust L.J. 791, 794 (1970).
  5. United States v. Westinghouse Elec. Co., 471 F. Supp. 532, 535 (N.D. Cal. 1978).
  6. 1 2 471 F. Supp. at 538.
  7. Timothy E. Kish, Antitrust Considerations in International Corporate Activity: Technical Assistance Agreements and Foreign Acquisitions, 12 B.C. Indus. & Com. L. Rev. 453, 454 (1971).
  8. 471 F. Supp. at 540.
  9. 471 F. Supp. at 541. Cf. Button-Fastener case#Sixth Circuit ruling; Motion Picture Patents Co. v. Universal Film Manufacturing Co.#The rise of the inherency doctrine.
  10. United States v. Westinghouse Elec. Corp., 648 F.2d 642, 645–46 (9th Cir. 1981). This legal theory had been articulated in 1971 in a journal article by Richard H. Stern, then chief of the patent unit in the Justice Department. See Note, Antitrust Problems in International Technology Transfers, 57 Wash. L. Rev. 745, 753 n.62 (1982) (citing Richard H. Stern, The Antitrust Status of Territorial Limitations in International Licensing, 14 IDEA 580 (1971).
  11. 648 F.2d at 646.
  12. 648 F.2d at 647 (citations omitted).
  13. 1 2 648 F.2d at 648.
  14. 1 2 648 F.2d at 649.
  15. See Stephen M. Hudspeth, Recent Developments in the Patent/Antitrust Interface – Response to a New Reality, 3 J.L. & Com. 35, 54 (1983).
  16. William M. Carley, "Cracking Down," Wall Street Journal, July 30, 1970, at 1, col. 6.
  17. Thomas V. Vakerics, Antitrust Basics § 11.02[9 at p. 11-4 n.153 (2013).
  18. Richard H. Stern, The Antitrust Status of Territorial Limitations in International Licensing, 14 IDEA 580 (1970)/
  19. Citing United States v. Masonite Corp. , 316 U.S. 265, 278 (1942).
  20. Id. at 581–82.
  21. 1 2 Id. at 583.
  22. Id. at 583–85.
  23. 334 U.S. 495 (1948).
  24. Id. at 588–89.
  25. Id. at 586.
  26. Howard L. Forman, Another View of the Antitrust Status of Territorial Limitations in International Licensing, 15 IDEA 27 (1971).
  27. Id. at 44.
  28. Id.
  29. Id. at 29 n.3.
  30. Id. at 30–31.
  31. Id. at 31.
  32. Douglas E. Rosenthal, Judicial Attitudes towards the Tensions between Antitrust, Federal Patent, and State Trade Secret Laws in International Technology Transfers, 50 Antitrust L.J. 525, 532 (1982).
  33. Id.
  34. Douglas E. Rosenthal, Stuart E. Benson, and Lisa Chiles, Doctrines and Problems Relating to U.S. Control of Transnational Corporate Concentration, 2 Mich. Y.B. Int'l Legal Studies 9 (1981).
  35. Id. at 17.
  36. Id.
  37. Id. at 17–18.
  38. Id. at 18.
  39. Id.
  40. Id. at 19.