Debt-to-GDP ratio

Last updated
Heatmap of the development of debt-to-GDP ratio for some European countries, in percent of GDP from 1995 to 2017. Gdp to debt ratio.svg
Heatmap of the development of debt-to-GDP ratio for some European countries, in percent of GDP from 1995 to 2017.

In economics, the debt-to-GDP ratio is the ratio between a country's government debt (measured in units of currency) and its gross domestic product (GDP) (measured in units of currency per year). A low debt-to-GDP ratio indicates that an economy produces goods and services sufficient to pay back debts without incurring further debt. [1] Geopolitical and economic considerations – including interest rates, war, recessions, and other variables – influence the borrowing practices of a nation and the choice to incur further debt. [2]

Contents

It should not be confused with a deficit-to-GDP ratio, which, for countries running budget deficits, measures a country's annual net fiscal loss in a given year (total expenditures minus total revenue, or the net change in debt per annum) as a percentage share of that country's GDP; for countries running budget surpluses, a surplus-to-GDP ratio measures a country's annual net fiscal gain as a share of that country's GDP.

Particularly in macroeconomics, various debt-to-GDP ratios can be calculated. The most commonly used ratio is the government debt divided by the gross domestic product (GDP), which reflects the government's finances, while another common ratio is the total debt to GDP, which reflects the finances of the nation as a whole.

The debt-to-GDP ratio is technically not a dimensionless quantity, but a unit of time, being equal to the amount of years over which the accumulated economic product equals the debt.

Changes

The change in debt-to-GDP is approximately "net change in debt as percentage of GDP";[ dubious discuss ] for government debt, this is deficit or (surplus) as percentage of GDP.[ dubious discuss ]

This is only approximate as GDP changes from year to year, but generally, year-on-year GDP changes are small (say, 3%),[ citation needed ] and thus this is approximately correct.[ dubious discuss ]

However, in the presence of significant inflation, or particularly hyperinflation, GDP may increase rapidly in nominal terms; if debt is nominal, then its ratio to GDP will decrease rapidly. A period of deflation would have the opposite effect.[ citation needed ]

A government's debt-to-GDP ratio can be analysed by looking at how it changes or, in other words, how the debt is evolving over time:

[ clarification needed ]

The left hand side of the equation demonstrates the dynamics of the government's debt. is the debt-to-GDP at the end of the period t, and is the debt-to-GDP ratio at the end of the previous period (t1). Hence, the left side of the equation shows the change in the debt-to-GDP ratio. The right hand side of the equation shows the causes of the government's debt.[ dubious discuss ] is the interest payments on the stock of debt as a ratio of GDP so far,[ citation needed ] and shows the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio.

If the government has the ability to print money, and therefore monetize the outstanding debt, the budget constraint becomes:

[ citation needed ]

The term is the change in money balances (i.e. money growth). By printing money the government is able to increase nominal money balances to pay off the debt (consequently acting in the debt way that debt financing does, in order to balance the government's expenditures).[ clarification needed ] However, the effect that an increase in nominal money balances has on seignorage is ambiguous, as while it increases the amount of money within the economy, the real value of each unit of money decreases due to inflationary effects. This inflationary effect from money printing is called an inflation tax. [3]

Applications

Debt-to-GDP measures the financial leverage of an economy.[ citation needed ]

One of the Euro convergence criteria was that government debt-to-GDP should be below 60%. [4]

The World Bank and the IMF hold that "a country can be said to achieve external debt sustainability if it can meet its current and future external debt service obligations in full, without recourse to debt rescheduling or the accumulation of arrears and without compromising growth".[ citation needed ] According to these two institutions, external debt sustainability can be obtained by a country "by bringing the net present value (NPV) of external public debt down to about 150 percent of a country's exports or 250 percent of a country's revenues". [5] High external debt is believed to have harmful effects on an economy. [6] The United Nations Sustainable Development Goal 17, an integral part of the 2030 Agenda has a target to address the external debt of highly indebted poor countries to reduce debt distress. [7]

In 2013 Herndon, Ash, and Pollin reviewed an influential, widely cited research paper entitled, "Growth in a Time of Debt", [8] by two Harvard economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff. Herndon, Ash and Pollin argued that "coding errors, selective exclusion of available data, and unconventional weighting of summary statistics lead to serious errors that inaccurately represent the relationship between public debt and GDP growth among 20 advanced economies in the post-war period". [9] [10] Correcting these basic computational errors undermined the central claim of the book that too much debt causes recession. [11] [12] Rogoff and Reinhardt claimed that their fundamental conclusions were accurate, despite the errors. [13] [14]

There is a difference between external debt denominated in domestic currency, and external debt denominated in foreign currency. A nation can service external debt denominated in domestic currency by tax revenues, but to service foreign currency debt it has to convert tax revenues in the foreign exchange market to foreign currency, which puts downward pressure on the value of its currency.

Global statistics

Debt to GDP for the United States
.mw-parser-output .legend{page-break-inside:avoid;break-inside:avoid-column}.mw-parser-output .legend-color{display:inline-block;min-width:1.25em;height:1.25em;line-height:1.25;margin:1px 0;text-align:center;border:1px solid black;background-color:transparent;color:black}.mw-parser-output .legend-text{}
State and local debt to GDP
Federal debt to GDP Debt to GDP.webp
Debt to GDP for the United States
   State and local debt to GDP
   Federal debt to GDP
European debt to GDP ratios
Greece
Italy
Spain
Portugal
France
Ireland
Germany
See also: European debt crisis European debt to GDP ratios.webp
European debt to GDP ratios
   Greece
   Italy
   Spain
   Portugal
   France
   Ireland
   Germany

At the end of the 1st quarter of 2021, the United States public debt-to-GDP ratio was 127.5%. [15] According to the IMF World Economic Outlook Database (April 2021), [16] the level of Gross Government debt-to-GDP ratio in Canada was 116.3%, in China 66.8%, in India 89.6%, in Germany 70.3%, in France 115.2% and in the United States 132.8%.

Two-thirds of US public debt is owned by US citizens, banks, corporations, and the Federal Reserve Bank; [17] approximately one-third of US public debt is held by foreign countries – particularly China and Japan. In comparison, less than 5% of Italian and Japanese public debt is held by foreign countries.

Convergence

Under a weak condition, the Debt-to-GDP ratio converges to a finite value. [18] Given utility function , where alpha is a propensity to consume , we have a period sequence for investment , government bond and output . We then have a relation

where are interest rate, inflation rate, and real growth rate, respectively. For the initial period, bond is given by . Then bond at t=n is expressed as

Taking account of , we obtain

which yields

This indicates that if the conditon is met, then the debt-to-GDP ratio converges. [18] For instance, if the propensity to consume is 0.4, then the condition for the convergence is , where is nominal growth rate.

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Bessel function</span> Families of solutions to related differential equations

Bessel functions, first defined by the mathematician Daniel Bernoulli and then generalized by Friedrich Bessel, are canonical solutions y(x) of Bessel's differential equation

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Taylor's theorem</span> Approximation of a function by a truncated power series

In calculus, Taylor's theorem gives an approximation of a -times differentiable function around a given point by a polynomial of degree , called the -th-order Taylor polynomial. For a smooth function, the Taylor polynomial is the truncation at the order of the Taylor series of the function. The first-order Taylor polynomial is the linear approximation of the function, and the second-order Taylor polynomial is often referred to as the quadratic approximation. There are several versions of Taylor's theorem, some giving explicit estimates of the approximation error of the function by its Taylor polynomial.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Hyperboloid</span> Unbounded quadric surface

In geometry, a hyperboloid of revolution, sometimes called a circular hyperboloid, is the surface generated by rotating a hyperbola around one of its principal axes. A hyperboloid is the surface obtained from a hyperboloid of revolution by deforming it by means of directional scalings, or more generally, of an affine transformation.

In mechanics and geometry, the 3D rotation group, often denoted SO(3), is the group of all rotations about the origin of three-dimensional Euclidean space under the operation of composition.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Beta distribution</span> Probability distribution

In probability theory and statistics, the beta distribution is a family of continuous probability distributions defined on the interval [0, 1] or in terms of two positive parameters, denoted by alpha (α) and beta (β), that appear as exponents of the variable and its complement to 1, respectively, and control the shape of the distribution.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Differential operator</span> Typically linear operator defined in terms of differentiation of functions

In mathematics, a differential operator is an operator defined as a function of the differentiation operator. It is helpful, as a matter of notation first, to consider differentiation as an abstract operation that accepts a function and returns another function.

In monetary economics, the money multiplier is the ratio of the money supply to the monetary base. If the money multiplier is stable, it implies that the central bank can control the money supply by determining the monetary base.

Algebraic geometry codes, often abbreviated AG codes, are a type of linear code that generalize Reed–Solomon codes. The Russian mathematician V. D. Goppa constructed these codes for the first time in 1982.

The Solow–Swan model or exogenous growth model is an economic model of long-run economic growth. It attempts to explain long-run economic growth by looking at capital accumulation, labor or population growth, and increases in productivity largely driven by technological progress. At its core, it is an aggregate production function, often specified to be of Cobb–Douglas type, which enables the model "to make contact with microeconomics". The model was developed independently by Robert Solow and Trevor Swan in 1956, and superseded the Keynesian Harrod–Domar model.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Beta prime distribution</span> Probability distribution

In probability theory and statistics, the beta prime distribution is an absolutely continuous probability distribution. If has a beta distribution, then the odds has a beta prime distribution.

In mathematics, in particular in algebraic geometry and differential geometry, Dolbeault cohomology (named after Pierre Dolbeault) is an analog of de Rham cohomology for complex manifolds. Let M be a complex manifold. Then the Dolbeault cohomology groups depend on a pair of integers p and q and are realized as a subquotient of the space of complex differential forms of degree (p,q).

In mathematics, a real or complex-valued function f on d-dimensional Euclidean space satisfies a Hölder condition, or is Hölder continuous, when there are real constants Template:''C'' ≥ 0, α > 0, such that for all x and y in the domain of f. More generally, the condition can be formulated for functions between any two metric spaces. The number is called the exponent of the Hölder condition. A function on an interval satisfying the condition with α > 1 is constant. If α = 1, then the function satisfies a Lipschitz condition. For any α > 0, the condition implies the function is uniformly continuous. The condition is named after Otto Hölder.

A ratio distribution is a probability distribution constructed as the distribution of the ratio of random variables having two other known distributions. Given two random variables X and Y, the distribution of the random variable Z that is formed as the ratio Z = X/Y is a ratio distribution.

In mathematics and mathematical physics, raising and lowering indices are operations on tensors which change their type. Raising and lowering indices are a form of index manipulation in tensor expressions.

In polynomial interpolation of two variables, the Padua points are the first known example of a unisolvent point set with minimal growth of their Lebesgue constant, proven to be . Their name is due to the University of Padua, where they were originally discovered.

In statistics, the backfitting algorithm is a simple iterative procedure used to fit a generalized additive model. It was introduced in 1985 by Leo Breiman and Jerome Friedman along with generalized additive models. In most cases, the backfitting algorithm is equivalent to the Gauss–Seidel method, an algorithm used for solving a certain linear system of equations.

Original sin is a term in economics literature, proposed by Barry Eichengreen, Ricardo Hausmann, and Ugo Panizza in a series of papers to refer to a situation in which "most countries are not able to borrow abroad in their domestic currency."

Growth in a Time of Debt, also known by its authors' names as Reinhart–Rogoff, is an economics paper by American economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff published in a non peer-reviewed issue of the American Economic Review in 2010. Politicians, commentators, and activists widely cited the paper in political debates over the effectiveness of austerity in fiscal policy for debt-burdened economies. The paper argues that when "gross external debt reaches 60 percent of GDP", a country's annual growth declined by two percent, and "for levels of external debt in excess of 90 percent" GDP growth was "roughly cut in half." Appearing in the aftermath of the financial crisis of 2007–2008, the evidence for the 90%-debt threshold hypothesis provided support for pro-austerity policies.

In mathematics, Mahler's 3/2 problem concerns the existence of "Z-numbers".

Magnetic materials with strong spin-orbit interaction, such as: LaFeAsO, PrFe4P12, YbRu2Ge2, UO2, NpO2, Ce1−xLaxB6, URu2Si2 and many other compounds, are found to have magnetic ordering constituted by high rank multipoles, e.g. quadruple, octople, etc. Due to the strong spin-orbit coupling, multipoles are automatically introduced to the systems when the total angular momentum quantum number J is larger than 1/2. If those multipoles are coupled by some exchange mechanisms, those multipoles could tend to have some ordering as conventional spin 1/2 Heisenberg problem. Except the multipolar ordering, many hidden order phenomena are believed closely related to the multipolar interactions

References

  1. Kenton, Will. "What the Debt-to-GDP Ratio Tells Us". Investopedia. Archived from the original on 2020-09-22. Retrieved 2020-09-22.
  2. "Budget Deficits and Interest Rates: What is the Link?". Federal Bank of St. Louis. Archived from the original on 2014-02-01. Retrieved 2013-10-09.
  3. Snowdon, Brian; Vane, Howard R. (11 April 2018). An Encyclopedia of Macroeconomics. Edward Elgar. p. 274. ISBN   9781840643879 . Retrieved 11 April 2018 via Google Books.
  4. "Convergence criteria". European Central Bank. 2020-07-10. Retrieved 2022-11-26.
  5. "The Challenge of Maintaining Long-Term External Debt Sustainability" (PDF). World Bank and International Monetary Fund . Archived (PDF) from the original on 2008-04-08.
  6. Bivens, L. Josh (December 14, 2004). "Debt and the dollar" (PDF). EPI Issue Brief (203). Economic Policy Institute. p. 2, "US external debt obligations". Archived from the original (PDF) on December 17, 2004. Retrieved July 8, 2007.
  7. "Goal 17 | Department of Economic and Social Affairs". sdgs.un.org. Archived from the original on 2020-09-22. Retrieved 2020-09-26.
  8. Krudy, Edward (18 April 2013). "How a student took on eminent economists on debt issue - and won". Reuters. Archived from the original on 26 January 2021. Retrieved 5 July 2021.
  9. Herndon, Thomas; Ash, Michael; Pollin, Robert (15 April 2013). "Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff" (PDF). PERI Working Paper Series (322). Political Economy Research Institute, University of Massachusetts Amherst. Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 April 2013. Retrieved 18 April 2013.
  10. Goldstein, Steve (April 16, 2013). "The spreadsheet error in Reinhart and Rogoff's famous paper on debt sustainability". MarketWatch . Archived from the original on November 29, 2014. Retrieved April 18, 2013.
  11. Alexander, Ruth (19 April 2013). "Reinhart, Rogoff... and Herndon: The student who caught out the profs". BBC News . Archived from the original on 20 April 2013. Retrieved 20 April 2013.
  12. "How Much Unemployment Was Caused by Reinhart and Rogoff's Arithmetic Mistake?". Center for Economic and Policy Research. April 16, 2013. Archived from the original on April 19, 2013. Retrieved April 18, 2013.
  13. Harding, Robin (16 April 2013). "Reinhart-Rogoff Initial Response". Financial Times. Archived from the original on 21 April 2013. Retrieved 25 April 2013.
  14. Inman, Phillip (April 17, 2013). "Rogoff and Reinhart defend their numbers". The Guardian . Archived from the original on October 18, 2013. Retrieved April 18, 2013.
  15. Federal Debt: Total Public Debt as Percent of Gross Domestic Product Archived 2017-02-20 at the Wayback Machine Federal Bank of St. Louis.
  16. International Monetary Fund: World Economic Outlook DatabaseGeneral government gross debt(Percent of GDP) Archived 2021-04-07 at the Wayback Machine
  17. "America's Foreign Creditors". The New York Times . 19 July 2011.
  18. 1 2 Tanaka, Y. (July 2022). "Debt to GDP ratio from the perspective of MMT with a simple macroeconomic foundation". Journal of Social Science Studies. 9.