Michael Dean Woodford

Last updated
Michael Woodford
Born1955 (age 6768)
NationalityAmerican
Academic career
Institution Columbia University
Field Macroeconomics
Monetary policy
School or
tradition
New Keynesian economics
Alma mater Yale University
MIT
University of Chicago
Doctoral
advisor
Timothy Kehoe [1]
Awards Deutsche Bank Prize (2007)
Information at IDEAS / RePEc

Michael Dean Woodford (born 1955) is an American macroeconomist and monetary theorist who currently teaches at Columbia University.

Contents

Academic career

Woodford holds B.A. from the University of Chicago (1977) and a J.D. from Yale Law School (1980). [2] He completed his Ph.D. in economics at MIT in 1983. [3]

He began his teaching career at Columbia, and then taught at Chicago and Princeton before returning to Columbia to accept the John Bates Clark chair in 2004. He was awarded the John D. and Catherine T. MacArthur Foundation Prize Fellowship, which financed his research from 1981 to 1986. In 2007, he was awarded the Deutsche Bank Prize. [4]

Theoretical contributions

Woodford's early research topics included sunspot equilibria, [5] and imperfect competition. [6] Thereafter he began to work on macroeconomic models with sticky prices; together with Julio Rotemberg he developed one of the first microfounded New Keynesian macroeconomic models. [7] Since then he has used this framework to study many topics related to monetary policy, including the fiscal theory of the price level, [8] the effectiveness of monetary policy as consumers use more credit and less cash, [9] and inflation targeting rules. [10] Michael Woodford has especially praised Knut Wicksell's advocacy of using the interest rate to maintain price stability, noting that this was a remarkable insight at a time when most monetary policy was based on the gold standard (Woodford, 2003, p. 32). Woodford calls his own framework 'neo-Wicksellian', and he titled his textbook on monetary policy in homage to Wicksell's work.

Interest and Prices

Woodford is probably best known as the author of an advanced textbook on monetary macroeconomics entitled Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. [11] [12] The book has, in the words of the Deutsche Bank Prize Committee, "quickly become the standard reference for monetary theory and analysis among academic economists and their colleagues at central banks." [4] The title Interest and Prices is a direct translation of Geldzins und Güterpreise the title of a book published by Wicksell in German 1898 and translated into English 1923. [13] [14]

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Macroeconomics</span> Study of an economy as a whole

Macroeconomics is a branch of economics that deals with the performance, structure, behavior, and decision-making of an economy as a whole. This includes regional, national, and global economies. Macroeconomists study topics such as output/GDP and national income, unemployment, price indices and inflation, consumption, saving, investment, energy, international trade, and international finance.

New Keynesian economics is a school of macroeconomics that strives to provide microeconomic foundations for Keynesian economics. It developed partly as a response to criticisms of Keynesian macroeconomics by adherents of new classical macroeconomics.

The quantity theory of money is a theory from monetary economics which states that the general price level of goods and services is directly proportional to the amount of money in circulation, and that the causality runs from money to prices. This implies that the theory potentially explains inflation. It originated in the 16th century and has been proclaimed the oldest surviving theory in economics.

A macroeconomic model is an analytical tool designed to describe the operation of the problems of economy of a country or a region. These models are usually designed to examine the comparative statics and dynamics of aggregate quantities such as the total amount of goods and services produced, total income earned, the level of employment of productive resources, and the level of prices.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Knut Wicksell</span> Swedish economist (1851–1926)

Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell was a Swedish economist of the Stockholm school. His economic contributions would influence both the Keynesian and Austrian schools of economic thought. He was married to the noted feminist Anna Bugge.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">John B. Taylor</span> American economist (born 1946).

John Brian Taylor is the Mary and Robert Raymond Professor of Economics at Stanford University, and the George P. Shultz Senior Fellow in Economics at Stanford University's Hoover Institution.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Thomas J. Sargent</span> American economist

Thomas John Sargent is an American economist and the W.R. Berkley Professor of Economics and Business at New York University. He specializes in the fields of macroeconomics, monetary economics, and time series econometrics. As of 2020, he ranks as the 29th most cited economist in the world. He was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 2011 together with Christopher A. Sims for their "empirical research on cause and effect in the macroeconomy".

In economics, the term sunspots refers to an extrinsic random variable, that is, a random variable that does not affect economic fundamentals. Sunspots can also refer to the related concept of extrinsic uncertainty, that is, economic uncertainty that does not come from variation in economic fundamentals. David Cass and Karl Shell coined the term sunspots as a suggestive and less technical way of saying "extrinsic random variable".

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Christopher A. Sims</span> American econometrician and macroeconomist

Christopher Albert Sims is an American econometrician and macroeconomist. He is currently the John J.F. Sherrerd '52 University Professor of Economics at Princeton University. Together with Thomas Sargent, he won the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 2011. The award cited their "empirical research on cause and effect in the macroeconomy".

David Ernest William Laidler is an English/Canadian economist who has been one of the foremost scholars of monetarism. He published major economics journal articles on the topic in the late 1960s and early 1970s. His book, The Demand for Money, was published in four editions from 1969 through 1993, initially setting forth the stability of the relationship between income and the demand for money and later taking into consideration the effects of legal, technological, and institutional changes on the demand for money. The book has been translated into French, Spanish, Italian, Japanese, and Chinese.

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium modeling is a macroeconomic method which is often employed by monetary and fiscal authorities for policy analysis, explaining historical time-series data, as well as future forecasting purposes. DSGE econometric modelling applies general equilibrium theory and microeconomic principles in a tractable manner to postulate economic phenomena, such as economic growth and business cycles, as well as policy effects and market shocks.

Phillip David Cagan was an American scholar and author. He was Professor of Economics Emeritus at Columbia University.

New classical macroeconomics, sometimes simply called new classical economics, is a school of thought in macroeconomics that builds its analysis entirely on a neoclassical framework. Specifically, it emphasizes the importance of rigorous foundations based on microeconomics, especially rational expectations.

The Deutsche Bank Prize in Financial Economics honors renowned researchers who have made influential contributions to the fields of finance and money and macroeconomics, and whose work has led to practical and policy-relevant results. It was awarded biannually from 2005 to 2015 by the Center for Financial Studies (CFS), in partnership with Goethe University Frankfurt, and is sponsored by Deutsche Bank Donation Fund. The award carried an endowment of €50,000, which was donated by the Stiftungsfonds Deutsche Bank im Stifterverband für die Deutsche Wissenschaft.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">History of macroeconomic thought</span>

Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not affect real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these "classical" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Julio Rotemberg</span> Argentine-American economist

Julio Jacobo Rotemberg was an Argentine/American economist at Harvard Business School. He was known for his collaboration with Michael Woodford on the first New Keynesian DSGE model, especially on monopolistic competition. He was also known for an alternative model of sticky prices.

The new neoclassical synthesis (NNS), which is now generally referred to as New Keynesian economics, and occasionally as the New Consensus, is the fusion of the major, modern macroeconomic schools of thought – new classical macroeconomics/real business cycle theory and early New Keynesian economics – into a consensus view on the best way to explain short-run fluctuations in the economy. This new synthesis is analogous to the neoclassical synthesis that combined neoclassical economics with Keynesian macroeconomics. The new synthesis provides the theoretical foundation for much of contemporary mainstream macroeconomics. It is an important part of the theoretical foundation for the work done by the Federal Reserve and many other central banks.

The Barnett critique, named for the work of William A. Barnett in monetary economics, argues that internal inconsistency between the aggregation theory used to produce monetary aggregates and the economic theory used to produce the models within which the aggregates are used are responsible for the appearance of unstable demand and supply for money. The Barnett critique has produced a long and growing literature on monetary aggregation and index number theory and the use of the resulting aggregates in econometric modeling and monetary policy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Emi Nakamura</span> American economist (born 1980)

Emi Nakamura is a Canadian-American economist. She is the Chancellor's Professor of Economics at University of California, Berkeley. Nakamura is a research associate and co-director of the Monetary Economics Program of the National Bureau of Economic Research, and a co-editor of the American Economic Review.

Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé is a German economist who currently works as a professor of economics at Columbia University. Schmitt-Grohé's research has been focused on macroeconomics as well as fiscal and monetary policy in open and closed economies. In 2004 she was awarded the Bernacer prize, for her research of monetary stabilization policies.

References

  1. Woodford, Michael (1983), Essays in intertemporal economics . Ph.D. dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
  2. "Curriculum Vitae MICHAEL WOODFORD July 2017" (PDF). columbia.edu.
  3. Woodford, Michael Dean (1983), Essays in Intertemporal Economics. Ph.D. dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
  4. 1 2 "Michael Woodford: The Prize Winner 2007". October 4, 2007.
  5. Woodford, Michael (1990). "Learning to believe in sunspots". Econometrica . 58 (2): 287–307. doi:10.2307/2938205. JSTOR   2938205.
  6. Rotemberg, Julio; Woodford, Michael (1995). "Dynamic general equilibrium models with imperfectly competitive product markets". In Cooley, Thomas (ed.). Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. Princeton University Press. ISBN   0-691-04323-X.
  7. Rotemberg, Julio J.; Woodford, Michael (1997). "An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy" (PDF). NBER Macroeconomics Annual. 12: 297–346. doi:10.1086/654340. JSTOR   3585236. S2CID   154438345.
  8. Woodford, Michael (2001). "Fiscal requirements for price stability" (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking . 33 (3): 669–728. doi:10.2307/2673890. JSTOR   2673890. S2CID   2836780.
  9. Woodford, Michael (1998). "Doing without money: controlling inflation in a post-monetary world" (PDF). Review of Economic Dynamics . 1 (1): 173–219. doi:10.1006/redy.1997.0006. S2CID   15413387.
  10. Giannoni, Marc P.; Woodford, Michael (2005). "Optimal inflation targeting rules". In Bernanke, Ben; Woodford, Michael (eds.). The Inflation-Targeting Debate . Chicago: University of Chicago Press. pp.  93–172. ISBN   0-226-04472-6.
  11. Woodford, Michael (2003). Interest and prices: Foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. ISBN   0-691-01049-8.
  12. Green, Edward (2005). "A review of Interest and Prices". Journal of Economic Literature . 43: 121–134. doi:10.1257/0022051053737799.
  13. kanopiadmin (2014-08-18). "Interest and Prices". Mises Institute. Retrieved 2021-11-16.
  14. Sanger, C. P.; Wicksell, Knut (September 1898). "Geldzins und Guterpreise" (PDF). The Economic Journal. 8 (31): 384. doi:10.2307/2956550. JSTOR   2956550.