Pedersen index

Last updated

The Pedersen index is a measure of political volatility in party systems. It was described by Mogens Pedersen in a paper published in 1979 entitled The Dynamics of European Party Systems: Changing Patterns of Electoral Volatility. [1]

Contents

What the index means

"The net change within the electoral party system resulting from individual vote transfers" [2]

Construction of the Index

The Pedersen index is calculated as

  

where is the percentage of party political party at election and for the consecutive election. To calculate the index, the percentage gains of the winning parties must be determined. The resulting index will be between 0 (no parties gained, and thus no parties lost either) and 100 (all the parties from the last election were reduced to zero votes), because for every gain there is an equal (in terms of percentage of votes) loss. In other words, the index is equal to the net percentage of voters who changed their votes. ("Net percentage," because if the only change is a Party A voter switching to Party B, and a Party B voter switching to Party A, there is no net volatility.) The index can also be constructed by summing the absolute values of all gains and all losses, and dividing this total by two.

The political volatility measured by the Pedersen index differs from the political volatility when parliamentary seats are considered due to the differing seats-to-votes ratios. The Pedersen index can overestimate the political volatility for countries with newly formed parliamentary groups made of previously existing political parties. Other measures [3] differ in their estimates of political volatility.

Example

Assume that in the first election the Blue Party won 65%, the Orange Party won 25%, and the Fuchsia Party won 10%. Furthermore, assume that in the second election the Blue Party won 65%, the Orange Party won 15%, and the Fuchsia Party won 20%.

Election\PartyBlueOrangeFuchsia
1st65%25%10%
2nd65%15%20%
Gain/Loss0-1010

The index would be equal to Blue gains (none) plus Orange's loss (10% since we do not consider sign differences) plus Fuchsia gains (10%). We then multiply it by 1/2 or divide by 2 for a total volatility of 10%.

If all three parties had disappeared in the next election, and been replaced by the Red Party (75%) and the Black Party (25%), the volatility would have been 100%: The first three lose all (100%) + the Red Party gaining 75% and the Black Party 25% since the previous election (when they both received no votes.) 100+100 = 200 -> divide by 2 = 100

Countries

The Pedersen indices for individual countries [4] are listed below, only the last available index is shown. The Pedersen index tends to decrease for some countries with increasing number of consecutive elections. [4]

CountryYearPedersen index
Flag of Argentina.svg  Argentina 201125.1
Flag of Austria.svg  Austria 20107.3
Flag of Australia (converted).svg  Australia 20107.3
Flag of Bolivia.svg  Bolivia 200935.9
Flag of Brazil.svg  Brazil 201018.2
Flag of Bulgaria.svg  Bulgaria 200939.9
Flag of Chile.svg  Chile 200913.9
Flag of Colombia.svg  Colombia 201015.9
Flag of Costa Rica.svg  Costa Rica 201029.0
Flag of the Czech Republic.svg  Czech Republic 201027.7
Flag of the Dominican Republic.svg  Dominican Republic 201032.3
Flag of Ecuador.svg  Ecuador 200933.0
Flag of Estonia.svg  Estonia 201132.5
Flag of El Salvador.svg  El Salvador 201215.5
Flag of Germany.svg  Germany 20098.3
Flag of Honduras.svg  Honduras 20097.8
Flag of Hungary.svg  Hungary 201025.1
Flag of Israel.svg  Israel 200920.9
Flag of India.svg  India 200925.1
Flag of Italy.svg  Italy 200815.2
Flag of Japan.svg  Japan 200914.2
Flag of Latvia.svg  Latvia 201136.4
Flag of Lithuania.svg  Lithuania 201239.7
Flag of North Macedonia.svg  Macedonia 201132.0
Flag of Malaysia.svg  Malaysia 200813.7
Flag of Mexico.svg  Mexico 200921.0
Flag of Mongolia.svg  Mongolia 200824.3
Flag of the Netherlands.svg  Netherlands 201013.4
Flag of Paraguay.svg  Paraguay 200825.6
Flag of Romania.svg  Romania 200836.9
Flag of Sweden.svg  Sweden 20098.4
Flag of Singapore.svg  Singapore 201110.8
Flag of South Korea.svg  South Korea 201229.3
Flag of the Republic of China.svg  Taiwan 201216.9
Flag of Thailand.svg  Thailand 201027.2
Flag of Trinidad and Tobago.svg  Trinidad and Tobago 201125.1
Flag of the United Kingdom.svg  United Kingdom 20107.6
Flag of the United States.svg  United States 20103.4
Flag of Uruguay.svg  Uruguay 200914.6
Flag of Venezuela.svg  Venezuela 201034.5

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Proportional representation</span> Voting system that makes outcomes proportional to vote totals

Proportional representation (PR) refers to any type of electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body. The concept applies mainly to political divisions among voters. The essence of such systems is that all votes cast – or almost all votes cast – contribute to the result and are effectively used to help elect someone. Under other election systems, a bare plurality or a scant majority are all that are used to elect candidates. PR systems provide balanced representation to different factions, reflecting how votes are cast.

The electoral threshold, or election threshold, is the minimum share of votes that a candidate or political party requires before they become entitled to representation or additional seats in a legislature.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">D'Hondt method</span> Method for allocating seats in parliaments

The D'Hondt method, also called the Jefferson method or the greatest divisors method, is an apportionment method for allocating seats in parliaments among federal states, or in proportional representation among political parties. It belongs to the class of highest-averages methods. Compared to ideal proportional representation, the D'Hondt method reduces somewhat the political fragmentation for smaller electoral district sizes, where it favors larger political parties over small parties.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Sainte-Laguë method</span> Proportional-representation electoral system

The Webster method, also called the Sainte-Laguë method, is a highest averages apportionment method for allocating seats in a parliament among federal states, or among parties in a party-list proportional representation system. The Sainte-Laguë method shows a more equal seats-to-votes ratio for different sized parties among apportionment methods.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Unionist Party (Scotland)</span> Former centre-right political party in Scotland

The Unionist Party was the main centre-right political party in Scotland between 1912 and 1965.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Elections in Denmark</span>

There are three types of elections in Denmark: elections to the national parliament, local elections, and elections to the European Parliament. Referendums may also be called to consult the Danish citizenry directly on an issue of national concern.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Hare quota</span> Electoral system quota formula

In the study of apportionment, the Harequota is the number of voters represented by each legislator under an idealized system of proportional representation, where every legislator represents an equal number of voters and where every vote is used to elect someone. The Hare quota is the total number of votes divided by the number of seats to be filled. The Hare quota was used in the original proposal for a single transferable vote system, and is still occasionally used, although it has since been largely supplanted by the Droop quota.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Red states and blue states</span> U.S. states that vote predominantly for Democrats (blue) or Republicans (red)

Starting with the 2000 United States presidential election, the terms "red state" and "blue state" have referred to US states whose voters vote predominantly for one party—the Republican Party in red states and the Democratic Party in blue states—in presidential and other statewide elections. By contrast, states where the vote fluctuates between the Democratic and Republican candidates are known as "swing states" or "purple states". Examining patterns within states reveals that the reversal of the two parties' geographic bases has happened at the state level, but it is more complicated locally, with urban-rural divides associated with many of the largest changes.

An electoral swing analysis shows the extent of change in voter support, typically from one election to another, expressed as a positive or negative percentage. A multi-party swing is an indicator of a change in the electorate's preference between candidates or parties, often between major parties in a two-party system. A swing can be calculated for the electorate as a whole, for a given electoral district or for a particular demographic.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Gallagher index</span> Measure of electoral disproportionality

The Gallagher index measures an electoral system's relative disproportionality between votes received and seats in a legislature. As such, it measures the difference between the percentage of votes each party gets and the percentage of seats each party gets in the resulting legislature, and it also measures this disproportionality from all parties collectively in any one given election. That collective disproportionality from the election is given a precise score, which can then be used in comparing various levels of proportionality among various elections from various electoral systems. The Gallagher index is a statistical analysis methodology utilised within political science, notably the branch of psephology.

In electoral systems, a wasted vote is any vote cast that is not "used" to elect a winner, and so is not represented in the outcome. However, the term is vague and ill-defined, having been used to refer to a wide variety of unrelated concepts and metrics. The precise definition of a wasted vote can have a major impact on the conclusions of an analysis. For example, under the narrowest possible definition of a wasted vote, the single transferable vote (STV) can be considered to waste zero votes. However, if the wasted vote definition is expanded even slightly, it is possible for up to 100% of STV votes to be classified as wasted because STV fails the unanimity criterion; that is, it is possible to elect a legislature that every single voter agrees is worse than some alternative.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Apportionment (politics)</span> Way to distribute seats in a legislative body

Apportionment is the process by which seats in a legislative body are distributed among administrative divisions, such as states or parties, entitled to representation. This page presents the general principles and issues related to apportionment. The page apportionment by country describes the specific practices used around the world. The page Mathematics of apportionment describes mathematical formulations and properties of apportionment rules.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1940 United States presidential election in California</span>

The 1940 United States presidential election in California took place on November 5, 1940, as part of the 1940 United States presidential election. State voters chose 22 representatives, or electors, to the Electoral College, who voted for president and vice president.

Swing, in the politics of the United Kingdom, is a number used as an indication of the scale of voter change between two political parties. It originated as a mathematical calculation for comparing the results of two Parliamentary constituencies. The UK uses a first-past-the-post voting system. The swing is the percentage of voter support minus the comparative percentage of voter support corresponding to the same electorate or demographic.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1920 United States presidential election in New Mexico</span>

The 1920 United States presidential election in New Mexico took place on November 2, 1920. All contemporary forty-eight States were part of the 1920 United States presidential election. Voters chose three electors to represent them in the Electoral College, which voted for President and Vice President.

The Sainte-Laguë index (SLI) measures an election’s disproportionality, the adherence to the one person, one vote principle of equal representation. This index assumes if the fraction of voters matches the fraction of seats, then perfect proportionality is achieved.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Comparison of voting rules</span> Comparative politics for electoral systems

A major branch of social choice theory is devoted to the comparison of electoral systems, otherwise known as social choice functions. Viewed from the perspective of political science, electoral systems are rules for conducting elections and determining winners from the ballots cast. From the perspective of economics, mathematics, and philosophy, a social choice function is a mathematical function that determines how a society should make choices, given a collection of individual preferences.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1892 United States presidential election in Georgia</span>

The 1892 United States presidential election in Georgia took place on November 8, 1892, as part of the wider United States presidential election. Voters chose 13 representatives, or electors, to the Electoral College, who voted for president and vice president.

Apportionment in the Hellenic Parliament refers to those provisions of the Greek electoral law relating to the distribution of Greece's 300 parliamentary seats to the parliamentary constituencies, as well as to the method of seat allocation in Greek legislative elections for the various political parties. The electoral law was codified for the first time through a 2012 Presidential Decree. Articles 1, 2, and 3 deal with how the parliamentary seats are allocated to the various constituencies, while articles 99 and 100 legislate the method of parliamentary apportionment for political parties in an election. In both cases, Greece uses the largest remainder method.

The seats-to-votes ratio, also known as the advantage ratio, is a measure of equal representation of voters. The equation for seats-to-votes ratio for a political party i is:

References

  1. Pedersen's paper
  2. W. Ascher and S. Tarrow, 'The Stability of Communist Electorates: Evidence from a Longitudinal Analysis of French and Italian Aggregate Data', American Journal of Political Science, 19/3 (1975), 48o-i.
  3. Emanuele, Vincenzo. "Dataset of Electoral Volatility and its internal components in Western Europe (1945-2015)." (2015).
  4. 1 2 "Institutionalization of party systems: a cross-regional approach using the Weighted Volatility Index, Eduardo Olivares Concha, Prepared for the Political Studies Association 64th Annual International Conference, Manchester, 2014" (PDF).