Paul Romer

Last updated

Paul Romer
Paul Romer in 2005.jpg
Romer in 2005
Chief Economist of the World Bank
In office
October 2016 24 January 2018
President Jim Yong Kim
Preceded by Kaushik Basu
Succeeded by Shanta Devarajan (Acting)
Personal details
Born
Paul Michael Romer

(1955-11-06) November 6, 1955 (age 65)
Denver, Colorado, U.S.
Education University of Chicago (SB, PhD)
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Queen's University
Awards Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (2018)
Scientific career
Fields Economics
Institutions New York University
Stanford University
UC Berkeley
University of Chicago
University of Rochester
Thesis Dynamic competitive equilibria with externalities, increasing returns and unbounded growth  (1983)
Doctoral advisor José Scheinkman
Robert Lucas Jr.
Other academic advisors Russell Davidson
Ivar Ekeland
Doctoral students Sérgio Rebelo
Maurice Kugler
Influences Joseph Schumpeter
Robert Solow
Website https://paulromer.net/

Paul Michael Romer (born November 6, 1955) [1] is an American economist who is a University Professor in Economics at New York University. [2] Romer is best known as the former Chief Economist of the World Bank and for co-receiving the 2018 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (shared with William Nordhaus) for his work in endogenous growth theory. [3] He also coined the term "mathiness," which he describes as misuse of mathematics in economic research.

Contents

Before joining NYU, Romer was a professor at the University of Chicago, the University of California, Berkeley, Stanford University's Graduate School of Business, [4] and the University of Rochester. [5] [6] Romer was chief economist and senior vice president of the World Bank until he resigned in January 2018 following a controversy arising from his claim of possible political manipulation of Chile's "ease of doing business" ranking. [7] [8] Romer took leave from his position as professor of economics at NYU when he joined the World Bank, and returned to NYU after his term. In addition, he has also been a researcher at the National Bureau of Economic Research, Stanford's Center for International Development, the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research, the Hoover Institution, as well as a fellow at the Center for Global Development. [5] [9]

Early life and education

Romer was born to former Colorado governor Roy Romer and Beatrice "Bea" Miller. He has four brothers and two sisters. One of his brothers, Chris Romer, is a former Colorado state senator. [10]

He graduated in 1973 [11] from Phillips Exeter Academy. He earned his Bachelor of Science in mathematics [12] and a PhD in economics in 1983, [1] both from the University of Chicago, after graduate studies at Massachusetts Institute of Technology from 1977 to 1979 and at Queen's University (Kingston, Canada) from 1979 to 1980. [13]

Career

Romer's most important work is in the field of economic growth, and he has made important contributions in the development of endogenous growth theory. He was named one of America's 25 most influential people by Time magazine in 1997, [14] and he was awarded the Horst Claus Recktenwald Prize in Economics in 2002. In 2015, he was recipient of the John R. Commons Award, given by the economics honor society Omicron Delta Epsilon. [15]

Academia

Romer's research on economic growth followed extensive studies of long-run growth during the 1950s and 1960s. [16] The Solow–Swan model, for example, established the primacy of technological progress in accounting for sustained increases in output per worker. His 1983 dissertation, supervised by José Scheinkman and Robert Lucas Jr., amounted to constructing mathematical representations of economies in which technological change is the result of the intentional actions of people, such as research and development. It led to two Journal of Political Economy articles published in 1986 and 1990, respectively, which started endogenous growth theory.

He taught at the University of Rochester, the University of Chicago, the University of California, Berkeley, Stanford University and New York University. [5]

Business

Romer temporarily left academia in 2001 to found Aplia, a company which produces online problem sets for college students; Aplia was purchased in 2007 by Cengage Learning.

He is credited with the quote "A crisis is a terrible thing to waste," which he said during a November 2004 venture-capitalist meeting in California. Although he was referring to the rapidly rising education levels in other countries compared to the United States, the quote became a rallying concept for economists and consultants looking for constructive opportunities amid the Great Recession. [17]

Charter cities

Romer has attempted to replicate the success of charter cities and make them an engine of economic growth in developing countries. He promoted this idea in a TED talk in 2009, [18] and he has argued that with better rules and institutions less developed nations can be set on a different and better trajectory for growth. [19] In his model, a host country would turn responsibility for a charter city over to a more developed trustee nation, which would allow for new rules of governance to emerge. People could "vote with their feet" for or against these rules. [10]

The government of Honduras considered creating charter cities, though without the oversight of a third-party government, which some argue is neo-colonialism. [10] Romer served as chair of a "transparency committee" but resigned in September 2012 when the Honduran government agency responsible for the project signed agreements with international developers without involvement of the committee. [20]

World Bank

He became World Bank Chief Economist in October 2016. He resigned on 24 January 2018, [7] [8] following a controversy in which he stated in an interview with The Wall Street Journal on January 12, [21] [8] that during the tenure of Chile's socialist President Michelle Bachelet from 2014 onwards, Chile's ranking for ease of doing business had been downgraded by the World Bank as a result of changes of methodology which he claimed may have been politically motivated, [8] a claim denied by the former World Bank economist responsible for compiling Chile's ranking, Chilean economist Augusto Lopez-Claros. [22] [23]

Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics

Paul Romer during Nobel press conference in Stockholm, December 2018 Paul Romer EM1B6039 (46234134401).jpg
Paul Romer during Nobel press conference in Stockholm, December 2018

Romer shared the 2018 Prize with William Nordhaus. [24] In choosing Romer as one of the 2018 economics laureates, the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences stated that he had shown "how knowledge can function as a driver of long-term economic growth. . . . [Prior macroeconomic studies] had not modelled how economic decisions and market conditions determine the creation of new technologies. Paul Romer solved this problem by demonstrating how economic forces govern the willingness of firms to produce new ideas and innovations." [3]

After receiving the prize, Romer described how he started thinking about the relationship between growth and innovation: "The question that I first asked was, why was progress . . . speeding up over time? It arises because of this special characteristic of an idea, which is if [a million people try] to discover something, if any one person finds it, everybody can use the idea." [25]

The same day he received the award, Romer married Caroline Weber, a professor of French Literature at Barnard College. [26]

Publications

See also

Related Research Articles

James Tobin American economist (1918-2002)

James Tobin was an American economist who served on the Council of Economic Advisers and consulted with the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and taught at Harvard and Yale Universities. He developed the ideas of Keynesian economics, and advocated government intervention to stabilize output and avoid recessions. His academic work included pioneering contributions to the study of investment, monetary and fiscal policy and financial markets. He also proposed an econometric model for censored dependent variables, the well-known Tobit model.

Milton Friedman American economist and statistician

Milton Friedman was an American economist and statistician who received the 1976 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his research on consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and the complexity of stabilization policy. With George Stigler and others, Friedman was among the intellectual leaders of the Chicago school of economics, a neoclassical school of economic thought associated with the work of the faculty at the University of Chicago that rejected Keynesianism in favor of monetarism until the mid-1970s, when it turned to new classical macroeconomics heavily based on the concept of rational expectations. Several students, young professors and academics who were recruited or mentored by Friedman at Chicago went on to become leading economists, including Gary Becker, Robert Fogel, Thomas Sowell and Robert Lucas Jr.

Kenneth Arrow American economist

Kenneth Joseph Arrow was an American economist, mathematician, writer, and political theorist. He was the joint winner of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with John Hicks in 1972.

Robert Lucas Jr. American economist

Robert Emerson Lucas Jr. is an American economist at the University of Chicago, where he is currently the John Dewey Distinguished Service Professor Emeritus in Economics and the College. Widely regarded as the central figure in the development of the new classical approach to macroeconomics, he received the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1995 "for having developed and applied the hypothesis of rational expectations, and thereby having transformed macroeconomic analysis and deepened our understanding of economic policy". He has been characterized by N. Gregory Mankiw as "the most influential macroeconomist of the last quarter of the 20th century." As of 2020, he ranks as the 11th most cited economist in the world.

John Hicks British economist

Sir John Hicks was a British economist. He is considered one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. The most familiar of his many contributions in the field of economics were his statement of consumer demand theory in microeconomics, and the IS–LM model (1937), which summarised a Keynesian view of macroeconomics. His book Value and Capital (1939) significantly extended general-equilibrium and value theory. The compensated demand function is named the Hicksian demand function in memory of him.

Robert Solow American economist

Robert Merton Solow, GCIH is an American economist whose work on the theory of economic growth culminated in the exogenous growth model named after him. He is currently Emeritus Institute Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, where he has been a professor since 1949. He was awarded the John Bates Clark Medal in 1961, the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1987, and the Presidential Medal of Freedom in 2014. Four of his PhD students, George Akerlof, Joseph Stiglitz, Peter Diamond and William Nordhaus later received Nobel Memorial Prizes in Economic Sciences in their own right.

Paul Samuelson American economist (1915–2009)

Paul Anthony Samuelson was an American economist. The first American to win the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, the Swedish Royal Academies stated, when awarding the prize in 1970, that he "has done more than any other contemporary economist to raise the level of scientific analysis in economic theory". Economic historian Randall E. Parker has called him the "Father of Modern Economics", and The New York Times considered him to be the "foremost academic economist of the 20th century".

Endogenous growth theory economic theory

Endogenous growth theory holds that economic growth is primarily the result of endogenous and not external forces. Endogenous growth theory holds that investment in human capital, innovation, and knowledge are significant contributors to economic growth. The theory also focuses on positive externalities and spillover effects of a knowledge-based economy which will lead to economic development. The endogenous growth theory primarily holds that the long run growth rate of an economy depends on policy measures. For example, subsidies for research and development or education increase the growth rate in some endogenous growth models by increasing the incentive for innovation.

The Chicago school of economics is a neoclassical school of economic thought associated with the work of the faculty at the University of Chicago, some of whom have constructed and popularized its principles. Milton Friedman and George Stigler are considered the leading scholars of the Chicago school.

Trickle-down economics Economic and political term

Trickle-down economics, also known as trickle-down theory or the horse and sparrow theory, is the economic proposition that taxes on businesses and the wealthy in society should be reduced as a means to stimulate business investment in the short term and benefit society at large in the long term. The same concept is embodied in the phrase “a rising tide lifts all boats.” In recent history, the term has been used by critics of supply-side economic policies, such as "Reaganomics". Whereas general supply-side theory favors lowering taxes overall, trickle-down theory more specifically advocates for a lower tax burden on the upper end of the economic spectrum. Empirical evidence shows that the proposition has never managed to achieve all of its stated goals as described by the Reagan administration.

Edward C. Prescott American economist

Edward Christian Prescott is an American economist. He received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 2004, sharing the award with Finn E. Kydland, "for their contributions to dynamic macroeconomics: the time consistency of economic policy and the driving forces behind business cycles". This research was primarily conducted while both Kydland and Prescott were affiliated with the Graduate School of Industrial Administration at Carnegie Mellon University. According to the IDEAS/RePEc rankings, he was the 19th most widely cited economist in the world in 2013. In August 2014, Prescott was appointed as an Adjunct Distinguished Economic Professor at the Australian National University (ANU) in Canberra, Australia.

John B. Taylor American economist

John Brian Taylor is the Mary and Robert Raymond Professor of Economics at Stanford University, and the George P. Shultz Senior Fellow in Economics at Stanford University's Hoover Institution.

Thomas J. Sargent American economist

Thomas John Sargent is an American economist and the W.R. Berkley Professor of Economics and Business at New York University. He specializes in the fields of macroeconomics, monetary economics, and time series econometrics. As of 2020, he ranks as the 29th most cited economist in the world. He was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 2011 together with Christopher A. Sims for their "empirical research on cause and effect in the macroeconomy".

Karl Shell is an American theoretical economist, specializing in macroeconomics and monetary economics.

Christopher A. Pissarides

Sir Christopher Antoniou Pissarides is a Cypriot economist. He is the School Professor of Economics & Political Science and Regius Professor of Economics at the London School of Economics, and Professor of European Studies at the University of Cyprus. His research focuses on topics of macroeconomics, notably labour, economic growth, and economic policy. In 2010, he was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics, jointly with Peter A. Diamond and Dale Mortensen, "for their analysis of markets with theory of search frictions."

William Nordhaus American economist

William Dawbney Nordhaus is an American economist, a Sterling Professor of Economics at Yale University, best known for his work in economic modeling and climate change, and one of the 2 recipients of the 2018 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. Nordhaus received the prize "for integrating climate change into long-run macroeconomic analysis".

Michael Kremer American economist and Nobel laureate

Michael Robert Kremer is an American development economist who is University Professor in Economics And Public Policy at the University of Chicago. He is the founding director of the Development Innovation Lab at the Becker Friedman Institute for Economics. Kremer served as the Gates Professor of Developing Societies at Harvard University until 2020. In 2019, he was jointly awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics, together with Esther Duflo and Abhijit Banerjee, "for their experimental approach to alleviating global poverty."

The Journal of Political Economy is a monthly peer-reviewed academic journal published by the University of Chicago Press. Established by James Laurence Laughlin in 1892, it covers both theoretical and empirical economics. In the past, the journal published quarterly from its introduction through 1905, ten issues per volume from 1906 through 1921, and bimonthly from 1922 through 2019. The editor-in-chief is Magne Mogstad.

History of macroeconomic thought Aspect of history

Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not affect real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these "classical" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle.

The Department of Economics is an academic department of the University of Oxford within the Social Sciences Division. Relatively recently founded in 1999, the department is located in the Norman Foster-designed Manor Road Building.

References

  1. 1 2 Romer, Paul Michael (1983). Dynamic competitive equilibria with externalities, increasing returns and unbounded growth (Ph.D.). The University of Chicago. OCLC   28795806. ProQuest   303206758.
  2. "Paul Romer". paulromer.net. Retrieved June 22, 2021.
  3. 1 2 "The Prize in Economic Sciences 2018 Press Release" (PDF). Nobelprize.org . October 8, 2018.
  4. "N.Y.U. Lands Top Economist for Cities Project". New York Times . May 27, 2011. Retrieved May 27, 2011.
  5. 1 2 3 "CV (PAUL M. ROMER)" (PDF). Retrieved October 11, 2019.
  6. "Paul Romer". paulromer.net. Retrieved October 8, 2018.
  7. 1 2 Donnan, Shawn (January 25, 2018). "Outspoken World Bank chief economist Paul Romer exits: Emails reveal clashes over issues ranging from grammar to methodology". Financial Times.
  8. 1 2 3 4 "World Bank economist Paul Romer quits after Chile comments". Reuters. January 24, 2018. Retrieved October 8, 2018.
  9. "Risk and Return". Hoover Digest. No. 2. 1996. Archived from the original on August 2, 2012.
  10. 1 2 3 "The Politically Incorrect Guide to Ending Poverty". The Atlantic . July–August 2010.
  11. "Paul Romer '73 awarded Nobel Prize in economics". Phillips Exeter Academy. November 8, 2018. Retrieved April 11, 2021.
  12. "Economist Paul Romer, SB'77, PhD'83, wins share of Nobel Prize". uchicago news. August 8, 2018.
  13. Warsh, David (2007). Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations . New York: Norton. pp.  196–201. ISBN   978-0-393-32988-9.
  14. "Time's 25 Most Influential Americans". Time Magazine . Time Inc. April 21, 1997. Retrieved December 21, 2007.
  15. "Omicron Delta Epsilon - the International Economics Honor Society".
  16. Solow, Robert M. (1994). "Perspectives on Growth Theory". Journal of Economic Perspectives . 8 (1): 45–54. doi: 10.1257/jep.8.1.45 . JSTOR   2138150.
  17. Rosenthal, Jack (July 31, 2009). "A Terrible Thing to Waste". The New York Times. Retrieved October 9, 2011.
  18. Paul Romer: Why the world needs charter cities, TED talk August 2009
  19. Gunn, Dwyer (September 29, 2009). "Can "Charter Cities" Change the World? A Q&A With Paul Romer". The New York Times. Retrieved May 22, 2010.
  20. "Plan for Charter City to Fight Honduras Poverty Loses Its Initiator". New York Times. September 30, 2012.
  21. Josh Zumbrun; Ian Talley (January 12, 2018). "World Bank Unfairly Influenced Its Own Competitiveness Rankings". Wall Street Journal. Retrieved October 8, 2018.
  22. "Chile complains of World Bank unfair treatment". BBC. January 15, 2018. Retrieved October 8, 2018. In an interview given to the Chilean newspaper El Mercurio, the World Bank economist who had been responsible for the rankings, Augusto Lopez-Claros, said changes in methodology "took place in a transparent and open context," denying any political bias.
  23. Oscar Medina; Andrew Rosati (January 13, 2018). "World Bank to Probe Chile's Business Ranking After Bias Alleged". Bloomberg. Retrieved October 8, 2018. Chilean economist Augusto Lopez-Claros, who was in charge of compiling Chile’s ranking for the World Bank report, said accusations of political manipulation were “wholly without merit.”
  24. Appelbaum, Binyamin (October 8, 2018). "2018 Nobel in Economics Awarded to William Nordhaus and Paul Romer". The New York Times.
  25. Kiernan, Paul; Sugden, Joanna (October 8, 2018). "Two Top U.S. Economists Win Nobel for Work on Growth and Climate: Research of William D. Nordhaus and Paul M. Romer has had immense impact on global policy making, the Academy says". The Wall Street Journal.
  26. Mallozzi, Vincent M. (December 11, 2018). "Arts Meets Science and Chemistry Wins the Day". The New York Times. Retrieved October 11, 2019.
Diplomatic posts
Preceded by
Kaushik Basu
Chief Economist of the World Bank
2016–2018
Succeeded by
Shanta Devarajan
Acting