Bayes correlated equilibrium

Last updated
Bayes correlated equilibrium
Solution concept in game theory
Relationship
Superset of Correlated equilibrium, Bayesian Nash equilibrium
Significance
Proposed by Dirk Bergemann, Stephen Morris

In game theory, a Bayes correlated equilibrium is a solution concept for static games of incomplete information. It is both a generalization of the correlated equilibrium perfect information solution concept to bayesian games, and also a broader solution concept than the usual Bayesian Nash equilibrium thereof. Additionally, it can be seen as a generalized multi-player solution of the Bayesian persuasion information design problem. [1]

Contents

Intuitively, a Bayes correlated equilibrium allows for players to correlate their actions in a way such that no player has an incentive to deviate for every possible type they may have. It was first proposed by Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris. [2]

Formal definition

Preliminaries

Let be a set of players, and a set of possible states of the world. A game is defined as a tuple , where is the set of possible actions (with ) and is the utility function for each player, and is a full support common prior over the states of the world.

An information structure is defined as a tuple , where is a set of possible signals (or types) each player can receive (with ), and is a signal distribution function, informing the probability of observing the joint signal when the state of the world is .

By joining those two definitions, one can define as an incomplete information game. [3] A decision rule for the incomplete information game is a mapping . Intuitively, the value of decision rule can be thought of as a joint recommendation for players to play the joint mixed strategy when the joint signal received is and the state of the world is .

Definition

A Bayes correlated equilibrium (BCE) is defined to be a decision rule which is obedient: that is, one where no player has an incentive to unilaterally deviate from the recommended joint strategy, for any possible type they may be. Formally, decision rule is obedient (and a Bayes correlated equilibrium) for game if, for every player , every signal and every action , we have


for all .

That is, every player obtains a higher expected payoff by following the recommendation from the decision rule than by deviating to any other possible action.

Relation to other concepts

Bayesian Nash equilibrium

Every Bayesian Nash equilibrium (BNE) of an incomplete information game can be thought of a as BCE, where the recommended joint strategy is simply the equilibrium joint strategy. [2]

Formally, let be an incomplete information game, and let be an equilibrium joint strategy, with each player playing . Therefore, the definition of BNE implies that, for every , and such that , we have


for every .

If we define the decision rule on as for all and , we directly get a BCE.

Correlated equilibrium

If there is no uncertainty about the state of the world (e.g., if is a singleton), then the definition collapses to Aumann's correlated equilibrium solution. [4] In this case, is a BCE if, for every , we have [1]

for every , which is equivalent to the definition of a correlated equilibrium for such a setting.

Bayesian persuasion

Additionally, the problem of designing a BCE can be thought of as a multi-player generalization of the Bayesian persuasion problem from Emir Kamenica and Matthew Gentzkow. [5] More specifically, let be the information designer's objective function. Then her ex-ante expected utility from a BCE decision rule is given by: [1]

If the set of players is a singleton, then choosing an information structure to maximize is equivalent to a Bayesian persuasion problem, where the information designer is called a Sender and the player is called a Receiver.

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Pauli matrices</span> Matrices important in quantum mechanics and the study of spin

In mathematical physics and mathematics, the Pauli matrices are a set of three 2 × 2 complex matrices that are traceless, Hermitian, involutory and unitary. Usually indicated by the Greek letter sigma, they are occasionally denoted by tau when used in connection with isospin symmetries.

In information geometry, the Fisher information metric is a particular Riemannian metric which can be defined on a smooth statistical manifold, i.e., a smooth manifold whose points are probability measures defined on a common probability space. It can be used to calculate the informational difference between measurements.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Cramér–Rao bound</span> Lower bound on variance of an estimator

In estimation theory and statistics, the Cramér–Rao bound (CRB) relates to estimation of a deterministic parameter. The result is named in honor of Harald Cramér and Calyampudi Radhakrishna Rao, but has also been derived independently by Maurice Fréchet, Georges Darmois, and by Alexander Aitken and Harold Silverstone. It is also known as Fréchet-Cramér–Rao or Fréchet-Darmois-Cramér-Rao lower bound. It states that the precision of any unbiased estimator is at most the Fisher information; or (equivalently) the reciprocal of the Fisher information is a lower bound on its variance.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Rabi cycle</span> Quantum mechanical phenomenon

In physics, the Rabi cycle is the cyclic behaviour of a two-level quantum system in the presence of an oscillatory driving field. A great variety of physical processes belonging to the areas of quantum computing, condensed matter, atomic and molecular physics, and nuclear and particle physics can be conveniently studied in terms of two-level quantum mechanical systems, and exhibit Rabi flopping when coupled to an optical driving field. The effect is important in quantum optics, magnetic resonance and quantum computing, and is named after Isidor Isaac Rabi.

In differential topology, the jet bundle is a certain construction that makes a new smooth fiber bundle out of a given smooth fiber bundle. It makes it possible to write differential equations on sections of a fiber bundle in an invariant form. Jets may also be seen as the coordinate free versions of Taylor expansions.

In quantum physics, the scattering amplitude is the probability amplitude of the outgoing spherical wave relative to the incoming plane wave in a stationary-state scattering process. At large distances from the centrally symmetric scattering center, the plane wave is described by the wavefunction

In mathematical physics and differential geometry, a gravitational instanton is a four-dimensional complete Riemannian manifold satisfying the vacuum Einstein equations. They are so named because they are analogues in quantum theories of gravity of instantons in Yang–Mills theory. In accordance with this analogy with self-dual Yang–Mills instantons, gravitational instantons are usually assumed to look like four dimensional Euclidean space at large distances, and to have a self-dual Riemann tensor. Mathematically, this means that they are asymptotically locally Euclidean hyperkähler 4-manifolds, and in this sense, they are special examples of Einstein manifolds. From a physical point of view, a gravitational instanton is a non-singular solution of the vacuum Einstein equations with positive-definite, as opposed to Lorentzian, metric.

In solid-state physics, the tight-binding model is an approach to the calculation of electronic band structure using an approximate set of wave functions based upon superposition of wave functions for isolated atoms located at each atomic site. The method is closely related to the LCAO method used in chemistry. Tight-binding models are applied to a wide variety of solids. The model gives good qualitative results in many cases and can be combined with other models that give better results where the tight-binding model fails. Though the tight-binding model is a one-electron model, the model also provides a basis for more advanced calculations like the calculation of surface states and application to various kinds of many-body problem and quasiparticle calculations.

In mathematics, the Weyl character formula in representation theory describes the characters of irreducible representations of compact Lie groups in terms of their highest weights. It was proved by Hermann Weyl. There is a closely related formula for the character of an irreducible representation of a semisimple Lie algebra. In Weyl's approach to the representation theory of connected compact Lie groups, the proof of the character formula is a key step in proving that every dominant integral element actually arises as the highest weight of some irreducible representation. Important consequences of the character formula are the Weyl dimension formula and the Kostant multiplicity formula.

The Newman–Penrose (NP) formalism is a set of notation developed by Ezra T. Newman and Roger Penrose for general relativity (GR). Their notation is an effort to treat general relativity in terms of spinor notation, which introduces complex forms of the usual variables used in GR. The NP formalism is itself a special case of the tetrad formalism, where the tensors of the theory are projected onto a complete vector basis at each point in spacetime. Usually this vector basis is chosen to reflect some symmetry of the spacetime, leading to simplified expressions for physical observables. In the case of the NP formalism, the vector basis chosen is a null tetrad: a set of four null vectors—two real, and a complex-conjugate pair. The two real members often asymptotically point radially inward and radially outward, and the formalism is well adapted to treatment of the propagation of radiation in curved spacetime. The Weyl scalars, derived from the Weyl tensor, are often used. In particular, it can be shown that one of these scalars— in the appropriate frame—encodes the outgoing gravitational radiation of an asymptotically flat system.

Phase-comparison monopulse is a technique used in radio frequency (RF) applications such as radar and direction finding to accurately estimate the direction of arrival of a signal from the phase difference of the signal measured on two separated antennas or more typically from displaced phase centers of an array antenna. Phase-comparison monopulse differs from amplitude-comparison monopulse in that the former uses displaced phase centers with a common beam pointing direction, while the latter uses a common phase center and displaced beam pointing directions.

In statistics, the multivariate t-distribution is a multivariate probability distribution. It is a generalization to random vectors of the Student's t-distribution, which is a distribution applicable to univariate random variables. While the case of a random matrix could be treated within this structure, the matrix t-distribution is distinct and makes particular use of the matrix structure.

The scattering length in quantum mechanics describes low-energy scattering. For potentials that decay faster than as , it is defined as the following low-energy limit:

In statistical decision theory, where we are faced with the problem of estimating a deterministic parameter (vector) from observations an estimator is called minimax if its maximal risk is minimal among all estimators of . In a sense this means that is an estimator which performs best in the worst possible case allowed in the problem.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Gravitational lensing formalism</span>

In general relativity, a point mass deflects a light ray with impact parameter by an angle approximately equal to

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Kicked rotator</span>

The kicked rotator, also spelled as kicked rotor, is a paradigmatic model for both Hamiltonian chaos and quantum chaos. It describes a free rotating stick in an inhomogeneous "gravitation like" field that is periodically switched on in short pulses. The model is described by the Hamiltonian

In quantum computing, the quantum phase estimation algorithm is a quantum algorithm to estimate the phase corresponding to an eigenvalue of a given unitary operator. Because the eigenvalues of a unitary operator always have unit modulus, they are characterized by their phase, and therefore the algorithm can be equivalently described as retrieving either the phase or the eigenvalue itself. The algorithm was initially introduced by Alexei Kitaev in 1995.

Partial-wave analysis, in the context of quantum mechanics, refers to a technique for solving scattering problems by decomposing each wave into its constituent angular-momentum components and solving using boundary conditions.

A non-expanding horizon (NEH) is an enclosed null surface whose intrinsic structure is preserved. An NEH is the geometric prototype of an isolated horizon which describes a black hole in equilibrium with its exterior from the quasilocal perspective. It is based on the concept and geometry of NEHs that the two quasilocal definitions of black holes, weakly isolated horizons and isolated horizons, are developed.

Pure inductive logic (PIL) is the area of mathematical logic concerned with the philosophical and mathematical foundations of probabilistic inductive reasoning. It combines classical predicate logic and probability theory. Probability values are assigned to sentences of a first-order relational language to represent degrees of belief that should be held by a rational agent. Conditional probability values represent degrees of belief based on the assumption of some received evidence.

References

  1. 1 2 3 Bergemann, Dirk; Morris, Stephen (2019). "Information Design: A Unified Perspective". Journal of Economic Literature. 57 (1): 44–95. doi:10.1257/jel.20181489. JSTOR   26673203.
  2. 1 2 Bergemann, Dirk; Morris, Stephen (2016). "Bayes correlated equilibrium and the comparison of information structures in games". Theoretical Economics. 11 (2): 487–522. doi:10.3982/TE1808. hdl: 10419/150284 .
  3. Gossner, Olivier (2000). "Comparison of Information Structures". Games and Economic Behavior. 30 (1): 44–63. doi:10.1006/game.1998.0706. hdl: 10230/596 .
  4. Aumann, Robert J. (1987). "Correlated Equilibrium as an Expression of Bayesian Rationality". Econometrica. 55 (1): 1–18. doi:10.2307/1911154. JSTOR   1911154.
  5. Kamenica, Emir; Gentzkow, Matthew (2011-10-01). "Bayesian Persuasion". American Economic Review. 101 (6): 2590–2615. doi:10.1257/aer.101.6.2590. ISSN   0002-8282.