Tragedy of the commons

Last updated
Industrial pollution is one of the consequences of operators ignoring their effect on the shared environment. DARK CLOUDS OF FACTORY SMOKE OBSCURE CLARK AVENUE BRIDGE - NARA - 550179.jpg
Industrial pollution is one of the consequences of operators ignoring their effect on the shared environment.

The tragedy of the commons is a concept which states that if many people enjoy unfettered access to a finite, valuable resource, such as a pasture, they will tend to overuse it and may end up destroying its value altogether. Even if some users exercised voluntary restraint, the other users would merely replace them, the predictable result being a "tragedy" for all. The concept has been widely discussed, and criticised, in economics, ecology and other sciences.

Contents

The metaphorical term is the title of a 1968 essay by ecologist Garrett Hardin. The concept itself did not originate with Hardin, but rather extends back to classical antiquity, being discussed by Aristotle.

The principal concern of Hardin's essay was overpopulation of the planet. To prevent the inevitable tragedy (he argued) it was necessary to reject the principle (supposedly enshrined in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights) according to which every family has a right to choose the number of its offspring, and to replace it by "mutual coercion, mutually agreed upon".

Some scholars have argued that over-exploitation of the common resource is by no means inevitable, since the individuals concerned may be able to achieve mutual restraint by consensus. Others have contended that the metaphor is inapposite because its exemplar – unfettered access to common land – did not exist historically, the right to exploit common land being controlled by law. The work of Elinor Ostrom, who received the Nobel Prize in Economics, is seen by some economists as having refuted Hardin's claims. [1] Hardin's views on over-population have been criticised as simplistic [2] and racist. [3]

Expositions

Cows on Selsley Common, UK. Lloyd used shared grazing of common land as an illustration of where abuse of rights could occur. Cows on Selsley Common - geograph.org.uk - 192472.jpg
Cows on Selsley Common, UK. Lloyd used shared grazing of common land as an illustration of where abuse of rights could occur.

Classical

The concept of unrestricted-access resources becoming spent, where personal use does not incur personal expense, has been discussed for millennia. Aristotle wrote that "That which is common to the greatest number gets the least amount of care. Men pay most attention to what is their own: they care less for what is common." [4]

Lloyd's pamphlet

In 1833, the English economist William Forster Lloyd published "Two Lectures on the Checks to Population", [5] a pamphlet that included a hypothetical example of over-use of a common resource. [6] This was the situation of cattle herders sharing a common parcel of land on which they were each entitled to let their cows graze.

He postulated that if a herder put more than his allotted number of cattle on the common, overgrazing could result. For each additional animal, a herder could receive additional benefits, while the whole group shared the resulting damage to the commons. [7] If all herders made this individually rational economic decision, the common could be depleted or even destroyed, to the detriment of all. [5]

Lloyd's pamphlet was written after the enclosure movement had eliminated the open field system of common property. Carl Dahlman and others have asserted that his description was historically inaccurate, pointing to the fact that the system endured for hundreds of years without producing the disastrous effects claimed by Lloyd. [8]

Garrett Hardin's article

In 1968, ecologist Garrett Hardin explored this social dilemma in his article "The Tragedy of the Commons", published in the journal Science . [9] The essay derived its title from the pamphlet by Lloyd, which he cites, on the over-grazing of common land: [10]

Therein is the tragedy. Each man is locked into a system that compels him to increase his herd without limit  in a world that is limited. Ruin is the destination toward which all men rush, each pursuing his own best interest in a society that believes in the freedom of the commons. Freedom in a commons brings ruin to all.

Garrett Hardin, The Tragedy of the Commons

Hardin discussed problems that cannot be solved by technical means, as distinct from those with solutions that require "a change only in the techniques of the natural sciences, [11] demanding little or nothing in the way of change in human values or ideas of morality". Hardin focused on human population growth, the use of the Earth's natural resources, and the welfare state. [12]

Hardin argued that if individuals relied on themselves alone, and not on the relationship between society and man, then people will treat other people as resources, which would lead to the world population growing and for the process to continue. [13] Parents breeding excessively would leave fewer descendants because they would be unable to provide for each child adequately. Such negative feedback is found in the animal kingdom. [12] Hardin said that if the children of improvident parents starved to death, if overbreeding was its own punishment, then there would be no public interest in controlling the breeding of families. [12]

Political inferences

Hardin blamed the welfare state for allowing the tragedy of the commons; where the state provides for children and supports over breeding as a fundamental human right, a Malthusian catastrophe is inevitable. Consequently, in his article, Hardin lamented the following proposal from the United Nations: [14]

The Universal Declaration of Human Rights describes the family as the natural and fundamental unit of society. [Article 16] [15] It follows that any choice and decision with regard to the size of the family must irrevocably rest with the family itself, and cannot be made by anyone else.

U Thant, Statement on Population by the Secretary-General of the United Nations [16]

In addition, Hardin also pointed out the problem of individuals acting in rational self-interest by claiming that if all members in a group used common resources for their own gain and with no regard for others, all resources would still eventually be depleted. Overall, Hardin argued against relying on conscience as a means of policing commons, suggesting that this favors selfish individuals – often known as free riders  – over those who are more altruistic. [17]

In the context of avoiding over-exploitation of common resources, Hardin concluded by restating Hegel's maxim (which was quoted by Engels), "freedom is the recognition of necessity". [18] He suggested that "freedom" completes the tragedy of the commons. By recognizing resources as commons in the first place, and by recognizing that, as such, they require management, Hardin believed that humans "can preserve and nurture other and more precious freedoms". [14]

The "Commons" as a modern resource concept

Hardin's article marked the mainstream acceptance of the term "commons" as used to connote a shared resource. [19] As Frank van Laerhoven and Elinor Ostrom have stated: "Prior to the publication of Hardin’s article on the tragedy of the commons (1968), titles containing the words 'the commons', 'common pool resources,' or 'common property' were very rare in the academic literature." [20] They go on to say: "In 2002, Barrett and Mabry conducted a major survey of biologists to determine which publications in the twentieth century had become classic books or benchmark publications in biology. [21] [22] They report that Hardin’s 1968 article was the one having the greatest career impact on biologists and is the most frequently cited". [23] However, the Ostroms point out that Hardin's analysis was based on crucial misconceptions about the nature of common property systems.

System archetype

Causal loop diagram of the "tragedy of the commons" Tragedy of the commons.PNG
Causal loop diagram of the "tragedy of the commons"

In systems theory, the commons problem is one of the ten most common system archetypes. The Tragedy of the Commons archetype can be illustrated using a causal loop diagram. [24]

Application

Metaphoric meaning

Like Lloyd and Thomas Malthus before him, Hardin was primarily interested in the problem of human population growth. But in his essay, he also focused on the use of larger (though finite) resources such as the Earth's atmosphere and oceans, as well as pointing out the "negative commons" of pollution (i.e., instead of dealing with the deliberate privatization of a positive resource, a "negative commons" deals with the deliberate commonization of a negative cost, pollution).

As a metaphor, the tragedy of the commons should not be taken too literally. The "tragedy" is not in the word's conventional or theatric sense, nor a condemnation of the processes that lead to it. Similarly, Hardin's use of "commons" has frequently been misunderstood, leading him to later remark that he should have titled his work "The Tragedy of the Unregulated Commons". [25] [26]

The metaphor illustrates the argument that free access and unrestricted demand for a finite resource ultimately reduces the resource through over-exploitation, temporarily or permanently. This occurs because the benefits of exploitation accrue to individuals or groups, each of whom is motivated to maximize the use of the resource to the point in which they become reliant on it, while the costs of the exploitation are borne by all those to whom the resource is available (which may be a wider class of individuals than those who are exploiting it). This, in turn, causes demand for the resource to increase, which causes the problem to snowball until the resource collapses (even if it retains a capacity to recover). The rate at which depletion of the resource is realized depends primarily on three factors: the number of users wanting to consume the common in question, the consumptive nature of their uses, and the relative robustness of the common. [27]

The same concept is sometimes called the "tragedy of the fishers", because fishing too many fish before or during breeding could cause stocks to plummet. [28]

Modern commons

An over-grazed landscape Fat tailed sheep, Afghanistan, 1976.jpg
An over-grazed landscape

The tragedy of the commons can be considered in relation to environmental issues such as sustainability. [29] The commons dilemma stands as a model for a great variety of resource problems in society today, such as water, forests, [30] fish, and non-renewable energy sources such as oil, gas, and coal.

Hardin's model posits that the tragedy of the commons may emerge if individuals prioritize self-interest. [31] Government regulations have been instituted to avert resource degradation. However, extensive research spanning decades highlights instances where community-level resource management, operating independently of government intervention, has effectively overseen common resources. In the United States, fishing communities employ a strategy wherein access to local fishing areas is restricted to accepted members, resembling a private, members-only club. Membership is sustained through fee payments, and outsiders are met with resistance, showcasing a quasi-privatized system.[ citation needed ]

Another case study involves beavers in Canada, historically crucial for natives who, as stewards, organized to hunt them for food and commerce. Non-native trappers, motivated by fur prices, contributed to resource degradation, wresting control from the indigenous population. Conservation laws enacted in the 1930s in response to declining beaver populations led to the expulsion of trappers, legal acknowledgment of natives, and enforcement of customary laws. This intervention resulted in productive harvests by the 1950s. [32]

Situations exemplifying the "tragedy of the commons" include the overfishing and destruction of the Grand Banks of Newfoundland, the destruction of salmon runs on rivers that have been dammed [33] (most prominently in modern times on the Columbia River in the Northwest United States and historically in North Atlantic rivers), and the devastation of the sturgeon fishery (in modern Russia, but historically in the United States as well). In terms of water supply, another example is the limited water available in arid regions (e.g., the area of the Aral Sea and the Los Angeles water system supply, especially at Mono Lake and Owens Lake).

In economics, an externality is a cost or benefit that affects a party who did not choose to incur that cost or benefit. [34] [35] Negative externalities are a well-known feature of the "tragedy of the commons". For example, driving cars has many negative externalities; these include pollution, carbon emissions, and traffic accidents. Every time Person A gets in a car, it becomes more likely that Person Z will suffer in each of those areas. [36] Economists often urge the government to adopt policies that "internalize" an externality. [37]

The tragedy of the commons can also refer to the idea of open data. [38] Anonymised data are crucial for useful social research and represent therefore a public resource  better said, a common good  which is liable to exhaustion. [39] Some feel that the law should provide a safe haven for the dissemination of research data, since it can be argued that current data protection policies overburden valuable research without mitigating realistic risks. [40]

An expansive application of the concept can also be seen in Vyse's [41] analysis of differences between countries in their responses to the COVID-19 pandemic. [42] Vyse argues that those who defy public health recommendations can be thought of as spoiling a set of common goods, [43] "the economy, the healthcare system, and the very air we breathe, [44] for all of us. In a similar vein, it has been argued that higher sickness and mortality rates from COVID-19 in individualistic cultures with less obligatory collectivism, [45] is another instance of the "tragedy of the commons".

Tragedy of the digital commons

In the past two decades, scholars have been attempting to apply the concept of the tragedy of the commons to the digital environment. However, between scholars there are differences on some very basic notions inherent to the tragedy of the commons: the idea of finite resources and the extent of pollution. [20] On the other hand, there seems to be some agreement on the role of the digital divide and how to solve a potential tragedy of the digital commons. [20]

Resources

Many digital resources have properties that make them vulnerable to the tragedy of the commons, including data, [46] virtual artifacts [47] and even limited user attention. [48] Closely related are the physical computational resources, such as CPU, RAM, and network bandwidth, that digital communities on shared servers rely upon and govern. [49] Some scholars argue that digital resources are infinite, and therefore immune to the tragedy of the commons, because downloading a file does not constitute the destruction of the file in the digital environment, [50] and because it can be replicated and disseminated throughout the digital environment. [51] However, it can still be considered a finite resource within the context of privacy laws and regulations that limit access to it. [52]

Finite digital resources can thus be digital commons. An example is a database that requires persistent maintenance, such as Wikipedia. As a non-profit, it survives on a network of people contributing to maintain a knowledge base without expectation of direct compensation. This digital resource will deplete as Wikipedia may only survive if it is contributed to and used as a commons. The motivation for individuals to contribute is reflective of the theory because, if humans act in their own immediate interest and no longer participate, then the resource becomes misinformed or depleted. Arguments surrounding the regulation and mitigation requirements for digital resources may become reflective of natural resources. [53] [54]

This raises the question whether one can view access itself as a finite resource in the context of a digital environment. Some scholars argue this point, often pointing to a proxy for access that is more concrete and measurable. [55] One such proxy is bandwidth, which can become congested when too many people try to access the digital environment. [51] [56] Alternatively, one can think of the network itself as a common resource which can be exhausted through overuse. [57] Therefore, when talking about resources running out in a digital environment, it could be more useful to think in terms of the access to the digital environment being restricted in some way; this is called information entropy. [58]

Pollution

In terms of pollution, there are some scholars who look only at the pollution that occurs in the digital environment itself. [59] They argue that unrestricted use of digital resources can cause an overproduction of redundant data which causes noise and corrupts communication channels within the digital environment. [51] Others argue that the pollution caused by the overuse of digital resources also causes pollution in the physical environment. [60] They argue that unrestricted use of digital resources causes misinformation, fake news, crime, and terrorism, as well as problems of a different nature such as confusion, manipulation, insecurity, and loss of confidence. [61] [62]

Digital divide and solutions

Scholars disagree on the particularities underlying the tragedy of the digital commons; however, there does seem to be some agreement on the cause and the solution. [20] The cause of the tragedy of the commons occurring in the digital environment is attributed by some scholars to the digital divide. [20] They argue that there is too large a focus on bridging this divide and providing unrestricted access to everyone. Such a focus on increasing access without the necessary restrictions causes the exploitation of digital resources for individual self-interest that is underlying any tragedy of the commons. [51] [56]

In terms of the solution, scholars agree that cooperation rather than regulation is the best way to mitigate a tragedy of the digital commons. [20] The digital world is not a closed system in which a central authority can regulate the users, as such some scholars argue that voluntary cooperation must be fostered. [56] This could perhaps be done through digital governance structure that motivates multiple stakeholders to engage and collaborate in the decision-making process. [62] Other scholars argue more in favor of formal or informal sets of rules, like a code of conduct, to promote ethical behavior in the digital environment and foster trust. [51] [63] Alternative to managing relations between people, some scholars argue that it is access itself that needs to be properly managed, which includes expansion of network capacity. [57]

Patents and technology

Patents are effectively a limited-time exploitation monopoly given to inventors. Once the period has elapsed, the invention is in principle free to all, and many companies do indeed commercialize such products, now market-proven. However, around 50% of all patent applications do not reach successful commercialization at all, often due to immature levels of components or marketing failures by the innovators. Scholars have suggested that since investment is often connected to patentability, such inactive patents form a rapidly growing category of underprivileged technologies and ideas that, under current market conditions, are effectively unavailable for use. [64] Thus, "Under the current system, people are encouraged to register new patents, and are discouraged from using publicly available patents." [64] :765 The case might be particularly relevant to technologies that are relatively more environmentally/human damaging but also somewhat costlier than other alternatives developed contemporaneously. [64] :766

Examples

More general examples (some alluded to by Hardin) of potential and actual tragedies include:

Clearing rainforest for agriculture in southern Mexico Lacanja burn.JPG
Clearing rainforest for agriculture in southern Mexico

Application to evolutionary biology

A parallel was drawn in 2006 between the tragedy of the commons and the competing behaviour of parasites that, through acting selfishly, eventually diminish or destroy their common host. [78] The idea has also been applied to areas such as the evolution of virulence or sexual conflict, where males may fatally harm females when competing for matings. [79]

The idea of evolutionary suicide, where adaptation at the level of the individual causes the whole species or population to be driven extinct, can be seen as an extreme form of an evolutionary tragedy of the commons. [80] [81] From an evolutionary point of view, the creation of the tragedy of the commons in pathogenic microbes may provide us with advanced therapeutic methods. [82] [83]

Microbial ecology studies have also addressed if resource availability modulates the cooperative or competitive behaviour in bacteria populations. When resources availability is high, bacterial populations become competitive and aggressive with each other, but when environmental resources are low, they tend to be cooperative and mutualistic. [84]

Ecological studies have hypothesised that competitive forces between animals are major in high carrying capacity zones (i.e., near the Equator), where biodiversity is higher, because of natural resources abundance. This abundance or excess of resources, causes animal populations to have "r" reproduction strategies (many offspring, short gestation, less parental care, and a short time until sexual maturity), so competition is affordable for populations. Also, competition could select populations to have "r" behaviour in a positive feedback regulation. [85]

Contrary, in low carrying capacity zones (i.e., far from the equator), where environmental conditions are harsh K strategies are common (longer life expectancy, produce relatively fewer offspring and tend to be altricial, requiring extensive care by parents when young) and populations tend to have cooperative or mutualistic behaviors. If populations have a competitive behaviour in hostile environmental conditions they mostly are filtered out (die) by environmental selection; hence, populations in hostile conditions are selected to be cooperative. [86]

Climate change

The effects of climate change have been given as a mass example of the tragedy of the commons. [87] This perspective proposes that the earth, being the commons, has suffered a depletion of natural resources without regard to the externalities, the impact on neighboring and future populations. The collective actions of individuals, organisations, and governments continue to contribute to environmental degradation. Mitigation of the long-term impacts and tipping points require strict controls or other solution, but this may come as a loss to different industries. The sustainability of population and industry growth is the subject of climate change discussion. The global commons of environmental resource consumption or selfishness, as in the fossil fuel industry has been theorised as not realistically manageable. This is due to the crossing of irreversible thresholds of impact before the costs are entirely realised. [88]

Commons dilemma

The commons dilemma is a specific class of social dilemma in which people's short-term selfish interests are at odds with long-term group interests and the common good. [89] In academia, a range of related terminology has also been used as shorthand for the theory or aspects of it, including resource dilemma, take-some dilemma, and common pool resource . [90]

Commons dilemma researchers have studied conditions under which groups and communities are likely to under- or over-harvest common resources in both the laboratory and field. Research programs have concentrated on a number of motivational, strategic, and structural factors that might be conducive to management of commons. [91]

In game theory, which constructs mathematical models for individuals' behavior in strategic situations, the corresponding "game", developed by Hardin, is known as the Commonize Costs – Privatize Profits Game (CC–PP game). [92]

Psychological factors

Kopelman, Weber, & Messick (2002), in a review of the experimental research on cooperation in commons dilemmas, identify nine classes of independent variables that influence cooperation in commons dilemmas: social motives, gender, payoff structure, uncertainty, power and status, group size, communication, causes, and frames. [93] They organize these classes and distinguish between psychological individual differences (stable personality traits) and situational factors (the environment). [94] Situational factors include both the task (social and decision structure) and the perception of the task. [95]

Empirical findings support the theoretical argument that the cultural group is a critical factor that needs to be studied in the context of situational variables. [96] [97] Rather than behaving in line with economic incentives, people are likely to approach the decision to cooperate with an appropriateness framework. [98] An expanded, four factor model of the Logic of Appropriateness, [99] [100] suggests that the cooperation is better explained by the question: "What does a person like me (identity) do (rules) in a situation like this (recognition) given this culture (group)?"

Strategic factors

Strategic factors also matter in commons dilemmas. One often-studied strategic factor is the order in which people take harvests from the resource. In simultaneous play, all people harvest at the same time, whereas in sequential play people harvest from the pool according to a predetermined sequence – first, second, third, etc. [101] There is a clear order effect in the latter games: the harvests of those who come first – the leaders – are higher than the harvest of those coming later – the followers. [102] The interpretation of this effect is that the first players feel entitled to take more. With sequential play, individuals adopt a first come-first served rule, whereas with simultaneous play people may adopt an equality rule. [103] Another strategic factor is the ability to build up reputations. [104] Research found that people take less from the common pool in public situations than in anonymous private situations. Moreover, those who harvest less gain greater prestige and influence within their group. [105]

Structural factors

Hardin stated in his analysis of the tragedy of the commons that "Freedom in a commons brings ruin to all." [106] One of the proposed solutions is to appoint a leader to regulate access to the common. [107] Groups are more likely to endorse a leader when a common resource is being depleted and when managing a common resource is perceived as a difficult task. [108] Groups prefer leaders who are elected, democratic, and prototypical of the group, and these leader types are more successful in enforcing cooperation. [109] A general aversion to autocratic leadership exists, although it may be an effective solution, possibly because of the fear of power abuse and corruption. [110]

The provision of rewards and punishments may also be effective in preserving common resources. [111] Selective punishments for overuse can be effective in promoting domestic water and energy conservation – for example, through installing water and electricity meters in houses. [111] Selective rewards work, provided that they are open to everyone. An experimental carpool lane in the Netherlands failed because car commuters did not feel they were able to organize a carpool. [112] The rewards do not have to be tangible. In Canada, utilities considered putting "smiley faces" on electricity bills of customers below the average consumption of that customer's neighborhood. [113]

Solutions

Articulating solutions to the tragedy of the commons is one of the main problems of political philosophy. [114] [115] In some situations, locals implement (often complex) social schemes that work well. [116] When these fail, there are many possible governmental solutions such as privatization, internalizing the externalities, and regulation. [116]

Non-governmental solution

Robert Axelrod contends that even self-interested individuals will often find ways to cooperate, because collective restraint serves both the collective and individual interests. [117] Anthropologist G. N. Appell criticized those who cited Hardin to "impos[e] their own economic and environmental rationality on other social systems of which they have incomplete understanding and knowledge." [118]

Political scientist Elinor Ostrom, who was awarded 2009's Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for her work on the issue, and others revisited Hardin's work in 1999. [119] They found the tragedy of the commons not as prevalent or as difficult to solve as Hardin maintained, since locals have often come up with solutions to the commons problem themselves. [120] For example, another group found that a commons in the Swiss Alps has been run by a collective of farmers there to their mutual and individual benefit since 1517, in spite of the farmers also having access to their own farmland. [121] In general, it is in the interest of the users of a commons to keep them functioning and so complex social schemes are often invented by the users for maintaining them at optimum efficiency. [122] [123] Another prominent example of this is the deliberative process of granting legal personhood to a part of nature, for example rivers, with the aim of preserving their water resources and prevent environmental degradation. This process entails that a river is regarded as its own legal entity that can sue against environmental damage done to it while being represented by an independently appointed guardian advisory group. [124] This has happened as a bottom-up process in New Zealand: Here debates initiated by the Whanganui Iwi tribe have resulted in legal personhood for the river. The river is considered as a living whole, stretching from mountain to sea and even includes not only the physical but also its metaphysical elements. [125]

Similarly, geographer Douglas L. Johnson remarks that many nomadic pastoralist societies of Africa and the Middle East in fact "balanced local stocking ratios against seasonal rangeland conditions in ways that were ecologically sound", reflecting a desire for lower risk rather than higher profit; in spite of this, [126] it was often the case that "the nomad was blamed for problems that were not of his own making and were a product of alien forces." [127] Independently finding precedent in the opinions of previous scholars such as Ibn Khaldun as well as common currency in antagonistic cultural attitudes towards non-sedentary peoples, [127] governments and international organizations have made use of Hardin's work to help justify restrictions on land access and the eventual sedentarization of pastoral nomads despite its weak empirical basis. [128] Examining relations between historically nomadic Bedouin Arabs and the Syrian state in the 20th century, Dawn Chatty notes that "Hardin's argument was curiously accepted as the fundamental explanation for the degradation of the steppe land" [129] in development schemes for the arid interior of the country, downplaying the larger role of agricultural overexploitation in desertification as it melded with prevailing nationalist ideology which viewed nomads as socially backward and economically harmful. [130]

Elinor Ostrom and her colleagues looked at how real-world communities manage communal resources, such as fisheries, land irrigation systems, and farmlands, and they identified a number of factors conducive to successful resource management. [131] One factor is the resource itself; resources with definable boundaries (e.g. land) can be preserved much more easily. [132] A second factor is resource dependence; there must be a perceptible threat of resource depletion, and it must be difficult to find substitutes. [133] The third is the presence of a community; small and stable populations with a thick social network and social norms promoting conservation do better. [122] A final condition is that there be appropriate community-based rules and procedures in place with built-in incentives for responsible use and punishments for overuse. [134] When the commons is taken over by non-locals, those solutions can no longer be used. [120]

Many of the economic and social structures recommended by Ostrom coincide with the structures recommended by anarchists, particularly green anarchism. [135] The largest contemporary societies that use these organizational strategies are the Rebel Zapatista Autonomous Municipalities and the Autonomous Administration of North and East Syria which have heavily been influenced by anarchism and other versions of libertarian and ecological socialism.

Individuals may act in a deliberate way to avoid consumption habits that deplete natural resources. This consciousness promotes the boycotting of products or brands and seeking alternative, more sustainable options.

Altruistic punishment

Various well-established theories, such as theory of kin selection and direct reciprocity, have limitations in explaining patterns of cooperation emerging between unrelated individuals and in non-repeatable short-term interactions. [136] [137] Studies have shown that punishment is an efficacious motivator for cooperation among humans. [138] [139]

Altruistic punishment entails the presence of individuals that punish defectors from a cooperative agreement, although doing so is costly and provides no material gain. These punishments effectively resolve tragedy of the commons scenarios by addressing both first-order free rider problems (i.e. defectors free riding on cooperators) and second-order free rider problems (i.e. cooperators free riding on work of punishers). [140] Such results can only be witnessed when the punishment levels are high enough.

While defectors are motivated by self-interest and cooperators feel morally obliged to practice self-restraint, punishers pursue this path when their emotions are clouded by annoyance and anger at free riders. [141]

Governmental solutions

Governmental solutions are used when the above conditions are not met (such as a community being larger than the cohesion of its social network). [142] Examples of government regulation include population control, privatization, regulation, and internalizing the externalities. [143]

Population control

In Hardin's essay, he proposed that the solution to the problem of overpopulation must be based on "mutual coercion, mutually agreed upon" and result in "relinquishing the freedom to breed". Hardin discussed this topic further in a 1979 book, Managing the Commons, co-written with John A. Baden. [144] [145] He framed this prescription in terms of needing to restrict the "reproductive right", to safeguard all other rights. Several countries have a variety of population control laws in place. [146]

In the context of United States policy debates, Hardin advocated restrictions on migration, particularly of non-whites. In a 1991 article, he stated

Popular anthropology came along with its dogma that all cultures are equally good, equally valuable. To say otherwise was to be narrow-minded and prejudiced, to be guilty of the sin of ethnocentrism. In time, a sort of Marxist-Hegelian dialectic took charge of our thinking: ethnocentrism was replaced by what we can only call ethnofugalism—a romantic flight away from our own culture. That which was foreign and strange, particularly if persecuted, became the ideal. Black became beautiful, and prolonged bilingual education replaced naturalization. Immigration lawyers grew rich serving their clients by finding ways around the law of the land to which they (the lawyers) owe their allegiance. Idealistic religious groups, claiming loyalty to a higher power than the nation, openly shielded and transported illegal immigrants. [147]

Privatization

One solution for some resources is to convert common good into private property (Coase 1960), giving the new owner an incentive to enforce its sustainability. [148] Libertarians and classical liberals cite the tragedy of the commons as an example of what happens when Lockean property rights to homestead resources are prohibited by a government. [149] They argue that the solution to the tragedy of the commons is to allow individuals to take over the property rights of a resource, that is, to privatize it. [150]

In England, this solution was attempted in the Inclosure Acts. According to Karl Marx in Das Kapital , this solution leads to increasing numbers of people being pushed into smaller and smaller pockets of common land which has yet to be privatised, thereby merely displacing and exacerbating the problem while putting an increasing number of people in precarious situations. [151] Economic historian Bob Allen coined the term "Engels' pause" to describe the period from 1790 to 1840, when British working-class wages stagnated and per-capita gross domestic product expanded rapidly during a technological upheaval. [152]

Regulation

In a typical example, governmental regulations can limit the amount of a common good that is available for use by any individual. [153] Permit systems for extractive economic activities including mining, fishing, hunting, livestock raising, and timber extraction are examples of this approach. [154] Similarly, limits to pollution are examples of governmental intervention on behalf of the commons. [155] This idea is used by the United Nations Moon Treaty, Outer Space Treaty and Law of the Sea Treaty as well as the UNESCO World Heritage Convention (treaty) which involves the international law principle that designates some areas or resources the Common Heritage of Mankind. [156] [157] [158]


German historian Joachim Radkau thought Hardin advocates strict management of common goods via increased government involvement or international regulation bodies. [159] An asserted impending "tragedy of the commons" is frequently warned of as a consequence of the adoption of policies which restrict private property and espouse expansion of public property. [160] [161]

Giving legal rights of personhood to objects in nature is another proposed solution. The idea of giving land a legal personality is intended to enable the democratic system of the rule of law to allow for prosecution, sanction, and reparation for damage to the earth. [162] For example, this has been put into practice in Ecuador in the form of a constitutional principle known as "Pacha Mama" (Mother Earth). [163]

Internalizing externalities

Privatization works when the person who owns the property (or rights of access to that property) pays the full price of its exploitation. [164] As discussed above negative externalities (negative results, such as air or water pollution, that do not proportionately affect the user of the resource) is often a feature driving the tragedy of the commons. [165] Internalizing the externalities, in other words ensuring that the users of resource pay for all of the consequences of its use, can provide an alternate solution between privatization and regulation. [166] One example is gasoline taxes which are intended to include both the cost of road maintenance and of air pollution. [167] This solution can provide the flexibility of privatization while minimizing the amount of government oversight and overhead that is needed. [168]

The mid-way solution

One of the significant actions areas which can dwell as potential solution is to have co-shared communities that have partial ownership from governmental side and partial ownership from the community. [169] By ownership, here it is referred to planning, sharing, using, benefiting and supervision of the resources which ensure that the power is not held in one or two hands only. [170] Since, involvement of multiple stakeholders is necessary responsibilities can be shared across them based on their abilities and capacities in terms of human resources, infrastructure development ability, and legal aspects, etc. [171]

Criticism

Commons in historical reality

Common land in Dartmoor, England c. 1813 (watercolor, J. M. W. Turner) Joseph Mallord William Turner - Dartmoor- The Source of the Tamar and the Torridge - Google Art Project.jpg
Common land in Dartmoor, England c.1813 (watercolor, J. M. W. Turner)

The status of common land in England as mentioned in Lloyd's pamphlet has been widely misunderstood.

Millions of acres were "common land", but this did not mean public land open to everybody, a popular fallacy. There was no such thing as ownerless land. Every parcel of "common" land had a legal owner, who was a private person or corporation. The owner was called the lord of the manor [172] (which, like landlord, was a legal term denoting ownership, not aristocratic status).

It was true that there were local people, called commoners, defined as those who had a legal right to use his land for some purpose of their own, typically grazing their animals. Certainly their rights were strong, because the lord was not entitled to build on his own land, or fence off any part of it, [173] [174] unless he could prove he had left enough pasture for the commoners. [175] But these individuals were not the general public at large: not everyone in the vicinity was a commoner. [176]

Furthermore the commoners' right to graze the lord's land with their animals was restricted by law - precisely in order to prevent overgrazing. [177] If overgrazing did nevertheless occur, which it sometimes did, it was because of incompetent or weak land management, [178] and not because of the pressure of an unlimited right to graze, which did not exist.

Hence Christopher Rodgers said that "Hardin's influential thesis on the 'tragedy of the commons' ... has no application to common land in England and Wales. It is based on a false premise". Rodgers, professor of law at Newcastle University, added:

Far from suffering a tragedy of the commons in Hardin's sense, common land .. was subject to common law principles of customary origin that promoted 'sustainable management'. These were expressed through property rights, in the form of qualifications on the resource use conferred by property entitlements, and were administered by local manor courts... Moreover, the administration of customary rules by the manor courts represented a wholly different means for organising the management of common resources than the model posited by Hardin, which stresses the need for exclusive ownership by either individuals or government in order to promote the effective management of the resource. [179]

Every productive unit ("manor") had a manorial court; without it, the manor ceased to exist. [180] Manorial courts could fine commoners, and the lord of the manor for that matter, [181] for breaches of customary law, e.g. grazing too many cattle on the land. Customary law varied locally. It could not be altered without the consent of the whole body of the commoners, [182] except by getting an Act of Parliament. [183]

By the time of Lloyd's pamphlet (1833) the majority of land in England had been enclosed and had ceased to be common land. [184] That which remained may not have been good agricultural land anyway, [185] or the best managed. Lloyd takes for granted that common lands were inferior [186] and argues his over-grazing theory to explain it. He does not examine other possible causes e.g. common land was difficult to drain, to keep disease-free, and to use for improved cattle breeding. [187]

Likewise, Susan Jane Buck Cox argues that the common land example used to argue this economic concept is on very weak historical ground, and misrepresents what she terms was actually the "triumph of the commons": [188] the successful common usage of land for many centuries. She argues that social changes and agricultural innovation, and not the behaviour of the commoners, led to the demise of the commons. [189] In a similar vein, Carl Dahlman argues that commons were effectively managed to prevent overgrazing. [190]

Others

Hardin's work is criticised as historically inaccurate in failing to account for the demographic transition, [191] and for failing to distinguish between common property and open access resources. [192] [193] Radical environmentalist Derrick Jensen claims the tragedy of the commons is used as propaganda for private ownership. [194] [195] He says it has been used by the political right wing to hasten the final enclosure of the "common resources" of third world and indigenous people worldwide, as a part of the Washington Consensus. [196] He argues that in true situations, those who abuse the commons would have been warned to desist and if they failed would have punitive sanctions against them. He says that rather than being called "The Tragedy of the Commons", it should be called "the Tragedy of the Failure of the Commons". [197]

Marxist geographer David Harvey has a similar criticism: "The dispossession of indigenous populations in North America by 'productive' colonists, for instance, was justified because indigenous populations did not produce value", [198] asking: "Why, for instance, do we not focus in Hardin's metaphor on the individual ownership of the cattle rather than on the pasture as a common?" [199]

Some authors, like Yochai Benkler, say that with the rise of the Internet and digitalisation, an economics system based on commons becomes possible again. [200] He wrote in his book The Wealth of Networks in 2006 that cheap computing power plus networks enable people to produce valuable products through non-commercial processes of interaction: "as human beings and as social beings, rather than as market actors through the price system". [201] He uses the term networked information economy to refer to a "system of production, distribution, and consumption of information goods characterized by decentralized individual action carried out through widely distributed, nonmarket means that do not depend on market strategies." [202] He also coined the term commons-based peer production for collaborative efforts based on sharing information. [203] Examples of commons-based peer production are Wikipedia, free and open source software and open-source hardware. [204]

Tragedy of the commons has served as a pretext for powerful private companies and/or governments to introduce regulatory agents or outsourcing on less powerful entities or governments, for the exploitation of their natural resources. [205] [206] [207] Powerful companies and governments can easily corrupt and bribe less powerful institutions or governments, to allow them exploit or privatize their resources, which causes more concentration of power and wealth in powerful entities. [208] This phenomenon is known as the resource curse. [209]

Other criticisms have focused on Hardin's racist and eugenicist views, claiming that his arguments are directed towards forcible population control, particularly for people of color. [210] [211]

Comedy of the commons

In certain cases, exploiting a resource more may be a good thing. Carol M. Rose, in a 1986 article, discussed the concept of the "comedy of the commons", where the public property in question exhibits "increasing returns to scale" in usage (hence the phrase, "the more the merrier"), [212] in that the more people use the resource, the higher the benefit to each one. Rose cites as examples commerce and group recreational activities. According to Rose, public resources with the "comedic" characteristic may suffer from under-investment rather than over usage. [213]

A modern example presented by Garrett Richards in environmental studies is that the issue of excessive carbon emissions can be tackled effectively only when the efforts are directly addressing the issues along with the collective efforts from the world economies. [214] Additionally, the more that nations are willing to collaborate and contribute resources, the higher the chances are for successful technological developments. [215]

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Environmental economics</span> Sub-field of economics

Environmental economics is a sub-field of economics concerned with environmental issues. It has become a widely studied subject due to growing environmental concerns in the twenty-first century. Environmental economics "undertakes theoretical or empirical studies of the economic effects of national or local environmental policies around the world. ... Particular issues include the costs and benefits of alternative environmental policies to deal with air pollution, water quality, toxic substances, solid waste, and global warming."

In economics, the free-rider problem is a type of market failure that occurs when those who benefit from resources, public goods and common pool resources do not pay for them or under-pay. Examples of such goods are public roads or public libraries or other services or utilities of a communal nature. Free riders are a problem for common pool resources because they may overuse it by not paying for the good. Consequently, the common pool resource may be under-produced, overused, or degraded. Additionally, it has been shown that despite evidence that people tend to be cooperative by nature, the presence of free-riders causes cooperation to deteriorate, perpetuating the free-rider problem.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Externality</span> In economics, an imposed cost or benefit

In economics, an externality or external cost is an indirect cost or benefit to an uninvolved third party that arises as an effect of another party's activity. Externalities can be considered as unpriced components that are involved in either consumer or producer market transactions. Air pollution from motor vehicles is one example. The cost of air pollution to society is not paid by either the producers or users of motorized transport to the rest of society. Water pollution from mills and factories is another example. All (water) consumers are made worse off by pollution but are not compensated by the market for this damage. A positive externality is when an individual's consumption in a market increases the well-being of others, but the individual does not charge the third party for the benefit. The third party is essentially getting a free product. An example of this might be the apartment above a bakery receiving some free heat in winter. The people who live in the apartment do not compensate the bakery for this benefit.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Exploitation of natural resources</span> Use of natural resources for economic growth

The exploitation of natural resources describes using natural resources, often non-renewable or limited, for economic growth or development. Environmental degradation, human insecurity, and social conflict frequently accompany natural resource exploitation. The impacts of the depletion of natural resources include the decline of economic growth in local areas; however, the abundance of natural resources does not always correlate with a country's material prosperity. Many resource-rich countries, especially in the Global South, face distributional conflicts, where local bureaucracies mismanage or disagree on how resources should be used. Foreign industries also contribute to resource exploitation, where raw materials are outsourced from developing countries, with the local communities receiving little profit from the exchange. This is often accompanied by negative effects of economic growth around the affected areas such as inequality and pollution

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Environmental sociology</span> Study of interactions between societies and their natural environments

Environmental sociology is the study of interactions between societies and their natural environment. The field emphasizes the social factors that influence environmental resource management and cause environmental issues, the processes by which these environmental problems are socially constructed and define as social issues, and societal responses to these problems.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Pastoralism</span> Branch of agriculture concerned with raising livestock

Pastoralism is a form of animal husbandry where domesticated animals are released onto large vegetated outdoor lands (pastures) for grazing, historically by nomadic people who moved around with their herds. The animal species involved include cattle, camels, goats, yaks, llamas, reindeer, horses, and sheep.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Garrett Hardin</span> American ecologist (1915–2003)

Garrett James Hardin was an American ecologist and microbiologist. He focused his career on the issue of human overpopulation, and is best known for his exposition of the tragedy of the commons in a 1968 paper of the same title in Science, which called attention to "the damage that innocent actions by individuals can inflict on the environment". He is also known for Hardin's First Law of Human Ecology: "We can never do merely one thing. Any intrusion into nature has numerous effects, many of which are unpredictable."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Commons</span> Shared resources

The commons is the cultural and natural resources accessible to all members of a society, including natural materials such as air, water, and a habitable Earth. These resources are held in common even when owned privately or publicly. Commons can also be understood as natural resources that groups of people manage for individual and collective benefit. Characteristically, this involves a variety of informal norms and values employed for a governance mechanism. Commons can also be defined as a social practice of governing a resource not by state or market but by a community of users that self-governs the resource through institutions that it creates.

In economics, a common-pool resource (CPR) is a type of good consisting of a natural or human-made resource system, whose size or characteristics makes it costly, but not impossible, to exclude potential beneficiaries from obtaining benefits from its use. Unlike pure public goods, common pool resources face problems of congestion or overuse, because they are subtractable. A common-pool resource typically consists of a core resource, which defines the stock variable, while providing a limited quantity of extractable fringe units, which defines the flow variable. While the core resource is to be protected or nurtured in order to allow for its continuous exploitation, the fringe units can be harvested or consumed.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Excludability</span> Degree to which consumption of a good can be restricted

In economics, excludability is the degree to which a good, service or resource can be limited to only paying customers, or conversely, the degree to which a supplier, producer or other managing body can prevent consumption of a good. In economics, a good, service or resource is broadly assigned two fundamental characteristics; a degree of excludability and a degree of rivalry.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Elinor Ostrom</span> American political economist (1933–2012)

Elinor Claire "Lin" Ostrom was an American political scientist and political economist whose work was associated with New Institutional Economics and the resurgence of political economy. In 2009, she was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for her "analysis of economic governance, especially the commons", which she shared with Oliver E. Williamson; she was the first woman to win the prize.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Common good (economics)</span> One of the four main types of goods

Common goods are defined in economics as goods that are rivalrous and non-excludable. Thus, they constitute one of the four main types based on the criteria:

In psychology, a social trap is a conflict of interest or perverse incentive where individuals or a group of people act to obtain short-term individual gains, which in the long run leads to a loss for the group as a whole. Social traps are the cause of countless environmental issues, including overfishing, energy "brownout" and "blackout" power outages during periods of extreme temperatures, the overgrazing of cattle on the Sahelian Desert, the destruction of the rainforest by logging interests and agriculture, and, most importantly, climate change.

A collective action problem or social dilemma is a situation in which all individuals would be better off cooperating but fail to do so because of conflicting interests between individuals that discourage joint action. The collective action problem has been addressed in political philosophy for centuries, but was more famously interpreted in 1965 in Mancur Olson's The Logic of Collective Action.

The Commonize Costs–Privatize Profits Game is a concept developed by the ecologist Garrett Hardin to describe a "game" widely played in matters of resource allocation. The concept is Hardin's interpretation of the closely related phenomenon known as the tragedy of the commons, and is referred to in political discourse as "privatizing profits and socializing losses."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Property rights (economics)</span> Economics concept

Property rights are constructs in economics for determining how a resource or economic good is used and owned, which have developed over ancient and modern history, from Abrahamic law to Article 17 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights. Resources can be owned by individuals, associations, collectives, or governments.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Common heritage of humanity</span> Principle of international law

Common heritage of humanity is a principle of international law that holds the defined territorial areas and elements of humanity's common heritage should be held in trust for future generations and be protected from exploitation by individual nation states or corporations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Overexploitation</span> Depleting a renewable resource

Overexploitation, also called overharvesting or ecological overshoot, refers to harvesting a renewable resource to the point of diminishing returns. Continued overexploitation can lead to the destruction of the resource, as it will be unable to replenish. The term applies to natural resources such as water aquifers, grazing pastures and forests, wild medicinal plants, fish stocks and other wildlife.

The term "knowledge commons" refers to information, data, and content that is collectively owned and managed by a community of users, particularly over the Internet. What distinguishes a knowledge commons from a commons of shared physical resources is that digital resources are non-subtractible; that is, multiple users can access the same digital resources with no effect on their quantity or quality.

The digital commons are a form of commons involving the distribution and communal ownership of informational resources and technology. Resources are typically designed to be used by the community by which they are created.

References

Notes

  1. Frischmann, Brett; Marciano, Alain; Ramello, Giordano (2019). "Retrospectives: Tragedy of the Commons after 50 Years". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 33 (4): 211–228. doi:10.1257/jep.33.4.211 . Retrieved 19 May 2024.
  2. Hunter, Lori; Prakash, Aseem (2019). "Hardin's oversimplification of population growth". Nature Sustainability. Retrieved 19 May 2024.
  3. "Garrett Hardin". Southern Poverty Law Center. Retrieved 30 August 2024.
  4. "An Ecolate View of the Human Predicament by Garrett Hardin". Garrett Hardin Society. The Garrett Hardin Society. Retrieved 2022-11-24.
  5. 1 2 Lloyd 1833.
  6. Thompson, Noel (2004-09-23). "Thompson, William (1775–1833), socialist and economist" . Oxford Dictionary of National Biography . Oxford Dictionary of National Biography (online ed.). Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/ref:odnb/27284.(Subscription or UK public library membership required.)
  7. Shields, Morgan William (2016). "Enhancing insect diversity in agricultural landscapes while providing multiple additional benefits". 2016 International Congress of Entomology. Entomological Society of America. doi:10.1603/ice.2016.111463 (inactive 1 November 2024).{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of November 2024 (link)
  8. Dahlman, Carl Johan (1980). The open field system and beyond: a property rights analysis of an economic institution. Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN   9780521228817.
  9. 1 2 Hardin 1968
  10. Zhong, Xianxin; He, Shaotang (1996-07-19). Hoover, Richard B; Walker Ii, Arthur B. C (eds.). "<title>High-resolution grazing incidence x-ray spectrometer and its characteristics</title>". Multilayer and Grazing Incidence X-Ray/EUV Optics III. 2805. SPIE: 156–157. Bibcode:1996SPIE.2805..156Z. doi:10.1117/12.245087. S2CID   119679290.
  11. "Problems Solved by Means of the Lagrangian Formalism", Analytical Mechanics, CRC Press, pp. 165–235, 2014-08-26, doi:10.1201/b17232-9, ISBN   978-0-429-06861-4 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  12. 1 2 3 Hardin 1968 , p. 1248: "it is the role of education to reveal to all the necessity of abandoning the freedom to breed. Only so, can we put an end to this aspect of the tragedy of the commons?"
  13. Zakas, Christina; Deutscher, Jennifer M.; Kay, Alex D.; Rockman, Matthew V. (10 September 2018). Nordborg, Magnus; Tautz, Diethard; Nordborg, Magnus; Tessmar, Kristin (eds.). "Decoupled maternal and zygotic genetic effects shape the evolution of development (Table 3. A number of individuals from each family were used in mapping crosses.)". eLife. 7: e37143. doi: 10.7554/elife.37143.009 .
  14. 1 2 Hardin, Garrett (2017), "Excerpts from 'The Tragedy of the Commons'", Environment and Society, NYU Press, pp. 202–212, doi: 10.2307/j.ctt1ht4vw6.33 , ISBN   978-1-4798-4474-6
  15. Nations, United (10 December 1948). "The Universal Declaration of Human Rights". United Nations. Retrieved 4 September 2011.
  16. United Nations. Dept. of Economic and Social Affairs. Population Division (2004). Levels and trends of contraceptive use as assessed in 2002. United Nations Publications. p. 126. ISBN   978-92-1-151399-8. some have argued that it may be inferred from the rights to privacy, conscience, health and well-being set forth in various United Nation's conventions […] Parents have a basic human right to determine freely and responsibly the number and spacing of their children (United Nations, 1968)
  17. Mendonça, Renata S.; Dahl, Christoph D.; Carvalho, Susana; Matsuzawa, Tetsuro; Adachi, Ikuma (31 July 2018). "Touch-screen-guided task reveals a prosocial choice tendency by chimpanzees (Pan troglodytes) | Figure 4: Proportion of the cumulative mean for combinations of two options: S-A, (selfish and altruistic), P-A (prosocial and altruistic) and P-S (prosocial and selfish) in Experiment 2 for five individuals (A) and Pan (B)". PeerJ. 6: e5315. doi: 10.7717/peerj.5315/fig-4 .
  18. James, David (2021-03-04), "Hegel and Marx on the Historical Necessity of the Terror", Practical Necessity, Freedom, and History, Oxford University Press, pp. 101–124, doi:10.1093/oso/9780198847885.003.0005, ISBN   978-0-19-884788-5 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  19. Xepapadeas, Anastasios (June 1995). "Managing the international commons: Resource use and pollution control". Environmental & Resource Economics. 5 (4): 375–391. doi:10.1007/bf00691575. ISSN   0924-6460. S2CID   153630734.
  20. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Nagle, Frank (2018). "The Digital Commons: Tragedy or Opportunity? A Reflection on the 50th Anniversary of Hardin's Tragedy of the Commons". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3301005. ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   158249954.
  21. Barrett, Gary W.; Mabry, Karen E. (2002). "Twentieth-Century Classic Books and Benchmark Publications in Biology". BioScience. 52 (3): 282. doi: 10.1641/0006-3568(2002)052[0282:tccbab]2.0.co;2 . ISSN   0006-3568. S2CID   86354323.
  22. Lisa, Lucas (2006). The research game in academic life. Open University Press. ISBN   978-0-335-22997-0. OCLC   245532963.
  23. van Laerhoven, Frank; Ostrom, Elinor (2007). "Traditions and Trends in the Study of the Commons" (PDF). International Journal of the Commons. 1 (1): 3–28. doi:10.18352/ijc.76. S2CID   18897696.
  24. Senge, Peter M.; Senge, Peter M. (1990). The Fifth Discipline: The Art and Practice of the Learning Organization. Doubleday/Currency. ISBN   978-0-385-26094-7.
  25. Hesse, Stephen (2006-07-26). "Will commons sense dawn again in time?". The Japan Times Online. Search.japantimes.co.jp. Retrieved 22 October 2013.
  26. Hardin 1998.
  27. Daniels, Brigham (2007). "Emerging Commons and Tragic Institutions". Environmental Law. 37 (3): 515–571 [536]. JSTOR   43267404. SSRN   1227745.
  28. Bowles, Samuel (2004). Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution. Princeton University Press. pp. 27–29. ISBN   978-1-4008-2931-6.
  29. Hawkshaw, Robert; Hawkshaw, Sarah; Sumaila, U. (2012-11-15). "The Tragedy of the 'Tragedy of the Commons': Why Coining Too Good a Phrase Can Be Dangerous". Sustainability. 4 (11): 3141–3150. doi: 10.3390/su4113141 . hdl: 10535/8775 . ISSN   2071-1050.
  30. Andersson, K. (1996). "The Tragedy of the Common Forest: Why the Pacific Northwest Forest Conflict is a 'No Technical Solution' Problem". Oregon Daily Emerald.
  31. Berkes, F.; Feeny, D.; McCay, B. J.; Acheson, J. M. (July 1989). "The benefits of the commons". Nature. 340 (6229): 91–93. Bibcode:1989Natur.340...91B. doi:10.1038/340091a0. ISSN   0028-0836. S2CID   4310769.
  32. Feit, Harvey A. (2005). "Re-cognizing Co-management as Co-governance: Visions and Histories of Conservation at James Bay". Anthropologica. 47 (2): 267–288. JSTOR   25606240.
  33. Hsu, Shi-Ling (2005). "What Is a Tragedy of the Commons? Overfishing and the Campaign Spending Problem". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.668723. ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   142253315.
  34. Trumbull, William N. (2009-04-22), "Who has Standing in Cost-Benefit Analysis?", Cost-Benefit Analysis and Public Policy, Oxford, UK: Blackwell Publishing Ltd., pp. 37–51, doi:10.1002/9781444307177.ch4, ISBN   978-1-4443-0717-7 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  35. Price, Richard (2018). Observations on the Importance of the American Revolution and the means of making it a benefit to the world. Hansebooks. ISBN   978-3-337-53529-2. OCLC   1189696999.
  36. Dubner, Stephen J.; Levitt, Steven D. (2008-04-20). "Not-So-Free Ride". The New York Times. Retrieved 2020-02-25.
  37. Jaeger, William. Environmental Economics for Tree Huggers and Other Skeptics , p. 80 (Island Press 2012): "Economists often say that externalities need to be 'internalized,' meaning that some action needs to be taken to correct this kind of market failure."
  38. Haire, Sandra (2012-06-08), "What Can SourceForge.net Data Alone Tell Us about Open-Source Software Commons?", Internet Success, The MIT Press, pp. 143–178, doi:10.7551/mitpress/9780262017251.003.0008, ISBN   978-0-262-01725-1 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  39. Taylor, Linnet (2018-06-19). "The ethics of big data as a public good: which public? Whose good?". Philosophical Transactions. Series A, Mathematical, Physical, and Engineering Sciences. 374 (2083). doi:10.31228/osf.io/r49yp. PMC   5124068 . PMID   28336800. S2CID   242083314 . Retrieved 2021-05-24.
  40. Yakowitz Bambauer, Jane (2011). "Tragedy of the Data Commons". Harvard Journal of Law and Technology. 25 (1). SSRN   1789749.
  41. Vyse, Stuart (2021). "The tragedy of our commons". Skeptical Inquirer . 45 (2): 20–24.
  42. "COVID-19 crisis response in MENA countries". OECD Policy Responses to Coronavirus (COVID-19). 2020-11-06. doi: 10.1787/4b366396-en . ISSN   2708-0676. S2CID   240621499.
  43. "Common Goods and Public Goods", Global Ethics and Global Common Goods, Bloomsbury Academic, 2015, doi:10.5040/9781474240062.ch-005, ISBN   978-1-4725-8084-9 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  44. Vyaznikov, V.E. (2018). "Reformation Of Public Healthcare System As Measure To Improve Healthcare And Economy". In Ardashkin, I. B.; Iosifovich, B. Vladimir; Martyushev, N. V. (eds.). Research Paradigms Transformation in Social Sciences. The European Proceedings of Social and Behavioural Sciences. Future Academy. pp. 1379–1385. doi:10.15405/epsbs.2018.12.168. S2CID   170065825.
  45. Maaravi, Yossi; Levy, Aharon; Gur, Tamar; Confino, Dan; Segal, Sandra (2021-02-11). ""The Tragedy of the Commons": How Individualism and Collectivism Affected the Spread of the COVID-19 Pandemic". Frontiers in Public Health. 9: 627559. doi: 10.3389/fpubh.2021.627559 . ISSN   2296-2565. PMC   7905028 . PMID   33643992.
  46. Hess, Charlotte; Ostrom, Elinor, eds. (2006). Understanding Knowledge as a Commons. doi:10.7551/mitpress/6980.001.0001. ISBN   9780262256346.,
  47. Castronova, Edward (2002). "On Virtual Economies". SSRN. doi:10.2139/ssrn.338500. S2CID   263755316.,
  48. "Managing the virtual commons: Cooperation and conflict in computer communities". Computer-Mediated Communication. John Benjamins. 26 June 1996. p. 109.
  49. Frey, Seth; Sumner, Robert W. (2019). "Emergence of integrated institutions in a large population of self-governing communities". PLOS ONE. 14 (7): e0216335. arXiv: 1804.10312 . Bibcode:2019PLoSO..1416335F. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0216335 . PMC   6622466 . PMID   31295260.
  50. Tzitzikas, Yannis; Marketakis, Yannis (2018), "The File MyContacts.con: On Reading Unknown Digital Resources", Cinderella's Stick, Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 147–153, doi:10.1007/978-3-319-98488-9_15, ISBN   978-3-319-98487-2 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  51. 1 2 3 4 5 Greco, Gian Maria; Floridi, Luciano (2004). "The tragedy of the digital commons". Ethics and Information Technology. 6 (2): 73–81. doi:10.1007/s10676-004-2895-2. ISSN   1388-1957. S2CID   5990776.
  52. Yakowitz Bambauer, Jane (2011). "Tragedy of the Data Commons". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1789749. ISSN   1556-5068.
  53. D. Anthony, S. W. Smith, and T. Williamson, "Explaining quality in internet collective goods: zealots and good samaritans in the case of Wikipedia", THanover : Dartmouth College, Technical Report, November 2005.
  54. Anthony, Denise; Smith, Sean W.; Williamson, Tim (April 2007), "The Quality of Open Source Production: Zealots and Good Samaritans in the Case of Wikipedia" (PDF), Technical Report TR2007-606, Dartmouth College, archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-06-06, retrieved 2011-05-29
  55. Kieńć, Witold (2017). "Authors from the periphery countries choose open access more often". Learned Publishing. 30 (2): 125–131. doi: 10.1002/leap.1093 . S2CID   20237315.
  56. 1 2 3 C. D., Springer (2009). "Avoiding a Tragedy: Information Literacy and the Tragedy of the Digital Commons". Library Philosophy and Practice. 5.
  57. 1 2 Gupta, A.; Jukic, B.; Parameswaran, M.; Stahl, D.O.; Whinston, A.B. (November–December 1997). "Streamlining the digital economy: how to avert a tragedy of the commons". IEEE Internet Computing. 1 (6): 38–46. doi:10.1109/4236.643935.
  58. "Chapter 5. Organizing Access to Digital Information Sources", Digital Libraries, Berlin, New York: Walter de Gruyter  K. G. Saur, pp. 109–128, 2004-01-28, doi:10.1515/9783598440052.109, ISBN   978-3-598-44005-2 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  59. Weis, Judith S. (2015-01-08), "Introduction to the Marine Environment and Pollution", Marine Pollution, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/wentk/9780199996698.003.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-999669-8 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  60. "Does pollution overrun anti-pollution?: Pollution efficiency and environmental management in Bangladesh", Water Resources and Environment, CRC Press, pp. 147–150, 2015-11-17, doi:10.1201/b19079-26, ISBN   978-0-429-22563-5 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  61. Faltesek, Dan (2020), "Fake News Fingerprints", Fake News, The MIT Press, pp. 165–178, doi:10.7551/mitpress/11807.003.0019, ISBN   978-0-262-35738-8, S2CID   241063966 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  62. 1 2 Almeida, Virgilio; Filgueiras, Fernando; Gaetani, Francisco; Almeida, Virgilio (2020-07-01). "Digital Governance and the Tragedy of the Commons". IEEE Internet Computing. 24 (4): 41–46. doi:10.1109/MIC.2020.2979639. ISSN   1089-7801. S2CID   221845343.
  63. Curien, Nicolas; Fauchart, Emmanuelle; Laffond, Gilbert; Moreau, François (2007), Brousseau, Eric; Curien, Nicolas (eds.), "Online consumer communities: escaping the tragedy of the digital commons", Internet and Digital Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 201–219, doi:10.1017/cbo9780511493201.006, ISBN   978-0-511-49320-1 , retrieved 2020-12-23
  64. 1 2 3 Sariel, Aviram, Daniel Mishori, and Joseph Agassi. "The re-inventor's dilemma: a tragedy of the public domain." Journal of Intellectual Property Law & Practice 10 (2015).
  65. "Global Warming and Ocean Acidification", Understanding Environmental Pollution, Cambridge University Press, pp. 133–165, 2020-07-09, doi:10.1017/9781108395021.008, ISBN   978-1-108-39502-1, S2CID   241103265 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  66. Madren, Carrie (August 31, 2010). "Dark nights: the global effort to tackle light pollution". The Ecologist. Retrieved 2020-02-24.
  67. Shiklomanov, Igor A. (2000). "Appraisal and Assessment of World Water Resources". Water International. 25 (1): 11–32. Bibcode:2000WatIn..25...11S. doi:10.1080/02508060008686794. S2CID   4936257.
  68. Wilson, E.O., 2002, The Future of Life, Vintage ISBN   0-679-76811-4
  69. Adler, Linus (2012), "Fossil Fuels", Encyclopedia of Global Warming & Climate Change, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications, Inc., doi:10.4135/9781452218564.n285, ISBN   978-1-4129-9261-9 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  70. Leakey, Richard and Roger Lewin, 1996, The Sixth Extinction : Patterns of Life and the Future of Humankind, Anchor, ISBN   0-385-46809-1
  71. Hogan, C. Michael (2014). Overfishing. Encyclopedia of Earth. National Council for Science and the Environment. eds. Sidney Draggan and C. Cleveland. Washington, D.C.
  72. ch 11–12. Mark Kurlansky, 1997. Cod: A Biography of the Fish That Changed the World, New York: Walker, ISBN   0-8027-1326-2.
  73. "Satellite constellations: Astronomers warn of threat to view of Universe". BBC. December 27, 2019. Retrieved February 3, 2020.
  74. O'Brien, Kieran S.; Blumberg, Seth; Enanoria, Wayne T. A.; Ackley, Sarah; Sippl-Swezey, Nicolas; Lietman, Thomas M. (2014). "Antibiotic Use as a Tragedy of the Commons: A Cross-Sectional Survey". Computational and Mathematical Methods in Medicine: 1–8. doi: 10.1155/2014/837929 . hdl: 10535/9382 .
  75. Hendrix, K. S.; Sturm, L. A.; Zimet, G. D.; Meslin, E. M. (2016). "Ethics and Childhood Vaccination Policy in the United States". American Journal of Public Health. 106 (2): 273–278. doi:10.2105/AJPH.2015.302952. PMC   4815604 . PMID   26691123. Section 3: The tragedy of the (herd immunity) commons.
  76. Prause, Christian R. (2011). "Reputation-based self-management of software process artifact quality in consortium research projects" (PDF). Proceedings of the 19th ACM SIGSOFT symposium and the 13th European conference on Foundations of software engineering – SIGSOFT/FSE '11. pp. 380–383. doi:10.1145/2025113.2025166. ISBN   978-1-4503-0443-6. S2CID   3101839.
  77. Stephane Kasriel (2017-07-31). "Skill, re-skill and re-skill again. How to keep up with the future of work". World Economic Forum.
  78. Dionisio, Francisco; Gordo, Isabel (2006). "The tragedy of the commons, the public goods dilemma, and the meaning of rivalry and excludability in evolutionary biology" (PDF). Evolutionary Ecology Research. 8: 321–332. hdl:10400.7/88. ISSN   1522-0613. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2007-09-27.
  79. Rankin, Daniel J.; Kokko, Hanna (2006). "Sex, death and tragedy" (PDF). Trends in Ecology & Evolution. 21 (5): 225–226. Bibcode:2006TEcoE..21..225R. doi:10.1016/j.tree.2006.02.013. PMID   16697906.
  80. Rankin, Daniel J. (2005). "Can adaptation lead to extinction?" (PDF). Oikos. 111 (3): 616–619. Bibcode:2005Oikos.111..616R. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.692.9713 . doi:10.1111/j.1600-0706.2005.14541.x. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-05-03.
  81. Rankin, Daniel J.; Bargum, Katja; Kokko, Hanna (2007). "The tragedy of the commons in evolutionary biology" (PDF). Trends in Ecology & Evolution. 22 (12): 643–651. Bibcode:2007TEcoE..22..643R. doi:10.1016/j.tree.2007.07.009. hdl:1975/7498. PMID   17981363.
  82. Ibrahim, Ahmed (2015). "The tragedy of the commons and prisoner's dilemma may improve our realization of the theory of life and provide us with advanced therapeutic ways". Figshare. doi:10.6084/m9.figshare.1533109.v8. S2CID   155620390.
  83. Oosterhout, Gretchen (2000). An Evolutionary Simulation of the Tragedy of the Commons (PhD dissertation). Portland State University. doi: 10.15760/etd.1250 .
  84. Hoek, Tim A.; Axelrod, Kevin; Biancalani, Tommaso; Yurtsev, Eugene A.; Liu, Jinghui; Gore, Jeff (2016-08-24). "Resource Availability Modulates the Cooperative and Competitive Nature of a Microbial Cross-Feeding Mutualism". PLOS Biology. 14 (8): e1002540. doi: 10.1371/journal.pbio.1002540 . ISSN   1545-7885. PMC   4996419 . PMID   27557335.
  85. Cardillo, Marcel (January 2002). "The life-history basis of latitudinal diversity gradients: how do species traits vary from the poles to the equator?". Journal of Animal Ecology. 71 (1): 79–87. Bibcode:2002JAnEc..71...79C. doi:10.1046/j.0021-8790.2001.00577.x. ISSN   0021-8790.
  86. Moore, Christopher M.; Catella, Samantha A.; Abbott, Karen C. (2017-02-13). Population dynamics of mutualism and intraspecific density dependence: howθ-logistic density dependence affects mutualistic positive feedback (Report). p. 108175. doi:10.1101/108175. S2CID   196627760 . Retrieved 2021-10-01.
  87. Ansari, Shahzad; Wijen, Frank; Gray, Barbara (August 2013). "Constructing a Climate Change Logic: An Institutional Perspective on the 'Tragedy of the Commons'". Organization Science. 24 (4). Providence, R.I.: 1014–1040. doi:10.1287/orsc.1120.0799. hdl: 1765/41166 . S2CID   18277351.
  88. Brown, Katrina; Adger, W. Neil; Cinner, Joshua E (January 2019). "Moving climate change beyond the tragedy of the commons". Global Environmental Change. 54: 61–63. Bibcode:2019GEC....54...61B. doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2018.11.009. hdl: 10871/35075 . S2CID   158760049.
  89. Druzin, Bryan (2016). "A Plan to strengthen the Paris Agreement". Fordham Law Review. 84: 19–20.
  90. Talloen, Joachim; Chapman, Gretchen B. (2014). "From Red Potato Chips to Greener Forests: Tackling a Common Pool Resource Dilemma with Partitions". PsycEXTRA Dataset. doi:10.1037/e573552014-013 . Retrieved 2021-05-24.
  91. "The open source software movement, the commons movement and seeds: what they have in common  biological open source and protected commons", Agrobiodiversity and the Law, Routledge, pp. 277–290, 2012-03-15, doi:10.4324/9780203155257-18 (inactive 1 November 2024), ISBN   978-0-203-15525-7 , retrieved 2021-05-24{{citation}}: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of November 2024 (link)
  92. "Game Theory and the Law Introduction", Applied Game Theory and Strategic Behavior, Chapman and Hall/CRC, pp. 191–214, 2016-04-19, doi:10.1201/9781584888444-14, ISBN   978-0-429-13663-4 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  93. Kopelman, Shirli (2008), "The Herdsman and the Sheep, Mouton, or Kivsa? The Influence of Group Culture on Cooperation in Social Dilemmas", New Issues and Paradigms in Research on Social Dilemmas, Boston: Springer US, pp. 177–188, doi:10.1007/978-0-387-72596-3_11, hdl: 2027.42/49422 , ISBN   978-0-387-72595-6 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  94. Goryńska, Ewa; Winiewski, Mikołaj; Zajenkowski, Marcin (April 2015). "Situational factors and personality traits as determinants of college students' mood". Personality and Individual Differences. 77: 1–6. doi:10.1016/j.paid.2014.12.027. ISSN   0191-8869.
  95. Kopelman, Weber & Messick 2002.
  96. Hartgen, David T. (December 1974). "Attitudinal and situational variables influencing urban mode choice: Some empirical findings". Transportation. 3 (4): 377–392. doi:10.1007/bf00167967. ISSN   0049-4488. S2CID   154764280.
  97. Gelfand & Dyer, 2000
  98. Weber, Kopelman & Messick 2004.
  99. Kopelman 2009.
  100. Myers, Christopher G.; Kopelman, Shirli (2012). "Cooperation between Cultures in the Commons: Implications for Cross-Cultural Interactions". Academy of Management Proceedings. 2012 (1). Briarcliff Manor, NY: 11042. doi:10.5465/AMBPP.2012.11042abstract. ISSN   2151-6561.
  101. Manheim, Jarol B. (2020-09-10), "All of the People, All the Time", All of the People All the Time, Routledge, pp. 235–241, doi:10.4324/9781003069768-11, ISBN   978-1-003-06976-8, S2CID   242175297 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  102. Doebel, Sabine (2019-04-24). "Good things come to those who wait: Delaying gratification likely does matter for later achievement". Psychological Science (preprint). doi:10.31234/osf.io/kbyna. S2CID   241276961 . Retrieved 2021-05-25.
  103. Swamidass, P. M. (2000). "First Come/First Served Rule (FCFS)". Encyclopedia of Production and Manufacturing Management. p. 207. doi:10.1007/1-4020-0612-8_330. ISBN   978-0-7923-8630-8.
  104. "India's conventional build-up". Strategic Comments. 10 (10): 1–2. December 2004. doi:10.1080/1356788041002. ISSN   1356-7888. S2CID   219695926.
  105. "Table 14. Graduates of each public and private medical college in private practice in the United States who are practicing in communities of less than 25,000 and those whose prior residence was in communities of less than 25,000, 1945 class". Academic Medicine. 1 (Supplement): 51–53. July 1956. doi: 10.1097/00001888-195607001-00015 . ISSN   1040-2446.
  106. Hardin 1968, p. 1244.
  107. "Access Audiology Tackles Auditory Processing and Common Core". The ASHA Leader. 19 (7): 58. July 2014. doi:10.1044/leader.an2.19072014.58. ISSN   1085-9586.
  108. Clarke, Harry (March 1995). "Optimal Depletion when Development Makes an Unused Resource Stock More Valuable". Natural Resource Modeling. 9 (2): 99–119. Bibcode:1995NRM.....9...99C. doi:10.1111/j.1939-7445.1995.tb00194.x. ISSN   0890-8575.
  109. ZHANG, Zheming; JIN, Shenghua; WU, Song; ZHOU, Xiang (2013-12-09). "The Influence of Leader on Group Member's Cooperation in Common Resource Dilemmas". Acta Psychologica Sinica. 45 (4): 453–465. doi:10.3724/sp.j.1041.2013.00453. ISSN   0439-755X. S2CID   147561539.
  110. Vassileva, Radosveta (2021). "COVID-19 in Autocratic Bulgaria: How the Anti-Corruption Protests Temporarily Limited the Abuse of Questionable Legislation". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3807883. ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   233708722.
  111. 1 2 "Rewards and punishments", Effective Classroom Management, Routledge, pp. 107–122, 2002-01-04, doi:10.4324/9780203130087-12, ISBN   978-0-203-13008-7 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  112. Van Vugt, M.; Van Lange, P. A. M.; Meertens, R. M.; Joireman, J. A. (1996). "How a Structural Solution to a Real-World Social Dilemma Failed: A Field Experiment on the First Carpool Lane in Europe" (PDF). Social Psychology Quarterly. 59 (4): 364–374. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.318.656 . doi:10.2307/2787077. JSTOR   2787077. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2017-08-09.
  113. "Put on a happy face, lower your electric bill". Toronto Sun. 2009-06-17. Archived from the original on 2009-06-17. Retrieved 2020-02-25.
  114. "One Man One Tree", Tragedy of the Commons (Poetry), Langaa RPCIG, p. 54, 2020-05-15, doi:10.2307/j.ctv12pnnrp.37, ISBN   978-9956-551-52-1, S2CID   243293265 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  115. Anukwonke, Charles (2015). The Concept of Tragedy of the Commons: Issues and Applications. doi:10.13140/RG.2.1.4977.9362.
  116. 1 2 OECD Economic Surveys: Sweden 2017 | Figure 2.9. Many women work part time, often involuntarily. doi:10.1787/888933446195 . Retrieved 2021-05-25.
  117. Axelrod, Robert (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation . New York: Basic Books. ISBN   978-0-465-02121-5.
  118. Appell, George N. (1993). Hardin's Myth of the Commons: The Tragedy of Conceptual Confusions. With Appendix: Diagrams of Forms of Co-ownership (PDF) (Working Paper). Phillips, ME: Social Transformation and Adaptation Research Institute. hdl: 10535/4532 .
  119. Ostrom, Elinor; Burger, Joanna; Field, Christopher B.; Norgaard, Richard B.; Policansky, David (1999). "Revisiting the Commons: Local Lessons, Global Challenges" (PDF). Science. 284 (5412): 278–282. Bibcode:1999Sci...284..278.. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.510.4369 . doi:10.1126/science.284.5412.278. PMID   10195886. S2CID   19472705. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2017-08-09. Retrieved 2018-07-23.
  120. 1 2 "Ostrom 'revisits the commons' in 'Science'". Archived from the original on 2012-03-05.
  121. Mathevet, Raphaël; Vuillot, Carole; Sirami, Clélia (2013-09-17). "Effective Nature Conservation on Farmland: Can We Change Our Own Models, Not Just the Farmers?". Conservation Letters. 7 (6): 575–576. doi: 10.1111/conl.12064 . ISSN   1755-263X. S2CID   83309993.
  122. 1 2 Elinor Ostrom: Beyond the tragedy of commons. Stockholm whiteboard seminars. (Video, 8:26 min.)
  123. Smith, Vernon L. (October 12, 2009). "Governing The Commons". Forbes. Retrieved 2020-02-25.
  124. Charpleix, Liz (March 2018). "The Whanganui River as Te Awa Tupua: Place-based law in a legally pluralistic society". The Geographical Journal. 184 (1): 19–30. Bibcode:2018GeogJ.184...19C. doi:10.1111/geoj.12238.
  125. O'Donnell, Erin L.; Talbot-Jones, Julia (2018). "Creating legal rights for rivers: lessons from Australia, New Zealand, and India". Ecology and Society. 23 (1): art7. doi: 10.5751/ES-09854-230107 . hdl: 1885/265550 . ISSN   1708-3087.
  126. Chatty, Dawn (2006-01-01), "Index", Nomadic Societies in the Middle East and North Africa, Brill: 1035–1060, doi:10.1163/9789047417750_040, ISBN   978-90-474-1775-0 , retrieved 2021-05-24
  127. 1 2 Johnson, Douglas L. (1993). "Nomadism and Desertification in Africa and the Middle East". GeoJournal. 31 (1): 51–66. doi:10.1007/bf00815903. S2CID   153445920.
  128. Lu, T.; Wu, N.; Luo, P. (October 2009). "Sedentarization of Tibetan Nomads". Conservation Biology. 23 (5): 1074. Bibcode:2009ConBi..23.1074L. doi:10.1111/j.1523-1739.2009.01312.x. ISSN   0888-8892. PMID   19765031. S2CID   19173099.
  129. Chatty, Dawn, ed. (2006-01-01). Nomadic Societies in the Middle East and North Africa. doi:10.1163/9789047417750. ISBN   978-90-474-1775-0.
  130. Chatty, Dawn (2010). "The Bedouin in Contemporary Syria: The Persistence of Tribal Authority and Control". Middle East Journal. 64 (1): 29–69. doi:10.3751/64.1.12. S2CID   143487962.
  131. Ostrom, Vincent; Ostrom, Elinor (1972). "Legal and Political Conditions of Water Resource Development". Land Economics. 48 (1): 1–14. doi:10.2307/3145634. ISSN   0023-7639. JSTOR   3145634. S2CID   152485064.
  132. "Can glass recycling pay for itself?". Resources Policy. 1 (5): 298. September 1975. doi:10.1016/0301-4207(75)90060-4. ISSN   0301-4207.
  133. "Resource development in western Canada: Indigenous peoples' human rights must be respected". Human Rights Documents online. doi:10.1163/2210-7975_hrd-5411-2014011 . Retrieved 2021-05-25.
  134. "Introduction: Defining Community-Built", Community-Built, New York: Routledge, pp. 15–34, 2016-11-25, doi:10.4324/9781315545066-7, ISBN   978-1-315-54506-6 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  135. Carson, Kevin (2013). "Governance, Agency and Autonomy: Anarchist Themes in the Work of Elinor Ostrom" (PDF). Center for a Stateless Society.
  136. Hamilton, W. D. (1964-07-01). "The genetical evolution of social behaviour. I". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 7 (1): 1–16. Bibcode:1964JThBi...7....1H. doi:10.1016/0022-5193(64)90038-4. ISSN   0022-5193. PMID   5875341. S2CID   5310280.
  137. Trivers, Robert L. (1971). "The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism". The Quarterly Review of Biology. 46 (1): 35–57. doi:10.1086/406755. ISSN   0033-5770. JSTOR   2822435. S2CID   19027999.
  138. Fehr, Ernst; Gächter, Simon (2002). "Altruistic punishment in humans". Nature. 415 (6868): 137–140. doi:10.1038/415137a. ISSN   1476-4687. PMID   11805825. S2CID   4310962.
  139. Balliet, Daniel; Mulder, Laetitia B.; Van Lange, Paul A. M. (2011). "Reward, punishment, and cooperation: a meta-analysis". Psychological Bulletin. 137 (4): 594–615. doi:10.1037/a0023489. ISSN   1939-1455. PMID   21574679. S2CID   2057071.
  140. Greenwood, Garrison W. (2016). "Altruistic punishment can help resolve tragedy of the commons social dilemmas". 2016 IEEE Conference on Computational Intelligence and Games (CIG). Santorini, Greece: IEEE. pp. 1–7. doi:10.1109/CIG.2016.7860402. ISBN   978-1-5090-1883-3. S2CID   14183178.
  141. Seip, Elise C.; van Dijk, Wilco W.; Rotteveel, Mark (2009). "On Hotheads and Dirty Harries: The Primacy of Anger in Altruistic Punishment". Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences. 1167 (1): 190–196. doi:10.1111/j.1749-6632.2009.04503.x. PMID   19580565. S2CID   11960190.
  142. "Being Too Big for Your Britches: So Much Confidence with So Little Talent (Experience)", It Sounded Good When We Started, IEEE, 2011, doi:10.1109/9780471723172.ch18, ISBN   978-0-471-72317-2 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  143. Moosa, Imad A. (2015), "Bad Regulation: Too Big to Fail, Bail-Out and Bail-In", Good Regulation, Bad Regulation, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 192–211, doi:10.1057/9781137447104_10, ISBN   978-1-349-68593-6 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  144. Chaddha, Shane (2011). "Hardin Goes to Outer Space  'Mutual Coercion, Mutually Agreed Upon By The Majority of People Affected'". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1763740. ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   154257809.
  145. "Managing the Commons by Garrett Hardin and John Baden". Ecobooks.com. Retrieved 22 October 2013.
  146. "Reproductive Rights as an International Norm", Global Population Policy, Routledge, pp. 135–166, 2017-07-05, doi:10.4324/9781315254180-5, ISBN   978-1-315-25418-0 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  147. Hardin, Garrett. "Conspicuous Benevolence and the Population Bomb". Chronicles. Retrieved 30 August 2024.
  148. Li, Hiu-yeung, Tony (2003). Owner Incorporation : a trick or a solution to private residential property management (Thesis). The University of Hong Kong Libraries. doi:10.5353/th_b3196942 (inactive 1 November 2024).{{cite thesis}}: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of November 2024 (link) CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  149. Smith, Robert J. (Fall 1981), Resolving the Tragedy of the Commons by Creating Private Property Rights in Wildlife (PDF), Cato Journal, vol. 1, Cato Institute, pp. 439–468
  150. John Locke, "Sect. 27" and following sections in Second Treatise of Government (1690). Also available here.
  151. Marx, Karl (1867), "Twenty-Seven: Expropriation of the Agricultural Population from the Land", Capital , vol. 1, Penguin UK
  152. Allen, Robert C. (2009). "Engels' pause: Technical change, capital accumulation, and inequality in the british industrial revolution". Explorations in Economic History. 46 (4): 418–435. doi:10.1016/j.eeh.2009.04.004.
  153. Wray, HA (1992), "Chapter 11: U.S. Governmental Regulatory Agencies Governmental Regulations", Manual on Flash Point Standards and Their Use: Methods and Regulations, West Conshohocken, PA: ASTM International, pp. 102–123, doi:10.1520/mnl10538m, ISBN   978-0-8031-1410-4 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  154. "Agriculture, Cattle-Raising, Hunting, and Fishing", Aegean Civilization, Routledge, pp. 181–191, 2013-10-28, doi:10.4324/9780203039915-11, ISBN   978-0-203-03991-5 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  155. Pieraccini, Margherita (2015-09-18). "Democratic legitimacy and new commons: examples from English protected areas". International Journal of the Commons. 9 (2): 552. doi: 10.18352/ijc.509 . ISSN   1875-0281.
  156. Frakes, Jennifer (2003). "The Common Heritage of Mankind Principle and Deep Seabed, Outer Space, and Antarctica: Will Developed and Developing Nations Reach a Compromise". Wisconsin International Law Journal. 21 (2): 409–434. HOL wisint21_18.
  157. Bin, Cheng (1997-12-18). "Part III United Nations Treaties on Outer Space, 9 The 1967 Space Treaty". Studies in International Space Law. doi:10.1093/law/9780198257301.003.0010.
  158. N., Scheiber, Harry (2000). Law of the sea : the common heritage and emerging challenges. Martinus Nijhoff Publishers. ISBN   90-411-1401-7. OCLC   44019679.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  159. Radkau, Joachim (2008). Nature and Power: A Global History of the Environment. Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-0-521-85129-9.
  160. Mirovitskaya, N.; Soroos, M. S. (January 1995). "Socialism and the Tragedy of the Commons: Reflections on Environmental Practice in the Soviet Union and Russia". The Journal of Environment & Development. 4 (1): 77–110. doi:10.1177/107049659500400105. S2CID   155028630.
  161. Perry, Mark (June 1995). "Why Socialism Failed". The Freeman . 45 (6). Archived from the original on 2009-06-29. Retrieved 2011-06-08.
  162. Hermitte, Marie-Angèle (2011). "La nature, sujet de droit ?". Annales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales. 66 (1): 173–212. doi:10.1017/S0395264900005503. S2CID   162165853 via CAIRN.
  163. Berros, María Valeria (2015-06-10). "The Constitution of the Republic of Ecuador: Pachamama Has Rights". Environment & Society Portal. doi:10.5282/rcc/7131.
  164. Who owns the intellectual property rights when an invention, copyright work or design is outsourced?. 2004-03-22. doi:10.18356/f2dc0688-en . Retrieved 2021-05-25.
  165. Hedge, A.; Collis, M. D. (1987-08-01). "Do Negative Air Ions Affect Human Mood and Performance?". The Annals of Occupational Hygiene. 31 (3): 285–290. doi:10.1093/annhyg/31.3.285. ISSN   1475-3162. PMID   3426028.
  166. "Externalities and Internalisation". Heliocene. 5 March 2021. Retrieved 2 Aug 2022.
  167. Austin, David; Dinan, Terry (2018-12-20), "Clearing the air: The costs and consequences of higher CAFE standards and increased gasoline taxes", Controlling Automobile Air Pollution, Routledge, pp. 449–469, doi:10.4324/9781351161084-23, ISBN   978-1-351-16108-4 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  168. Fullerton, Don; West, Sarah E. (2018-12-20), "Can Taxes on Cars and on Gasoline Mimic an Unavailable Tax on Emissions? 1", Controlling Automobile Air Pollution, Routledge, pp. 243–266, doi:10.4324/9781351161084-13, ISBN   978-1-351-16108-4, S2CID   239069281 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  169. Quan, Qi; Huyghebaert, Nancy (2007). "Ownership Dynamics After Partial Privatization: Evidence from China". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.966679. ISSN   1556-5068.
  170. "China: Designing policies and laws to ensure fair access and benefit sharing of genetic resources and participatory plant breeding products", The Custodians of Biodiversity, Routledge, pp. 120–146, 2012-03-15, doi:10.4324/9780203156032-21 (inactive 1 November 2024), ISBN   978-0-203-15603-2 , retrieved 2021-05-25{{citation}}: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of November 2024 (link)
  171. Pisani, Assunta, ed. (2018-10-24). Euro-Librarianship: Shared Resources, Shared Responsibilities. Routledge. doi:10.4324/9781315859590. ISBN   978-1-315-85959-0. S2CID   239912609.
  172. Hoskins 1963 , p. 4
  173. Hoskins 1963 , pp. 5–6
  174. Scrutton 1887 , p. 60
  175. Halsbury's Laws of England 1903 , pp. 505–506
  176. Hoskins 1963 , p. 4
  177. Hoskins, W.G. (2015). "Common land and its origin". In Hoskins, W.G.; Stamp, L. Dudley (eds.). The Common Lands of England and Wales. HarperCollins. ISBN   9780007342228.
  178. Scrutton 1887 , pp. 121–123
  179. Rodgers, Christopher (2010). "Reversing the 'Tragedy' of the Commons? Sustainable Management and the Commons Act 2006". The Modern Law Review. 73 (3): 461–486. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-2230.2010.00802.x . JSTOR   40660736.. pp. 462, 463
  180. Scrutton 1887 , p. 18
  181. Scrutton 1887 , p. 21
  182. Hoskins 1963 , p. 4
  183. For the disputed origins of manorial and commons law, and whether it came from ancient folk customs or from grants by early landowners, see Scrutton 1887 , pp. 1–41; Hoskins 1963 , pp. 5–8, 27–34.
  184. Scrutton 1887 , pp. 113–114
  185. Hoskins 1963 , p. xv.
  186. "Why are the cattle on a common so puny and stunted? Why is the common itself so bare-worn, and cropped so differently from the adjoining inclosures?": Lloyd 1833 , [30]–[31]
  187. Scrutton 1887 , pp. 115–121
  188. Cox, Susan Jane Buck (1985). "No Tragedy of the Commons". Environmental Ethics. 7 (1): 49–61. doi:10.5840/enviroethics1985716. ISSN   0163-4275.
  189. Cox, Susan Jane Buck (1985). "No Tragedy on the Commons" (PDF). Environmental Ethics. 7 (1): 49–61. doi:10.5840/enviroethics1985716. hdl: 10535/3113 .
  190. Dasgupta, Partha (2001). Human Well-Being and the Natural Environment. Oxford University Press. ISBN   978-0-19-924788-2.
  191. Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.; Bishop, Richard (1975). "Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resources Policy". Natural Resources Journal. 15 (4): 713–727. ISSN   0028-0739.
  192. Rowe, Jonathan (2008). "The parallel Economy of the Commons". State of the World 2008: Innovation for a Sustainable Development. London: Earthscan: 142.
  193. Puzon, Klarizze; Willinger, Marc (2019). "Can Common Ownership Prevent the Tragedy of the Commons? An Experimental Investigation". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3410383. ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   201461194.
  194. Jensen, Derrick (2007), "Endgame Vol 1: The Problem of Civilization" and "Endgame Vol II: Resistance" (Seven Stories Press)
  195. Looney, Robert E. (1988), "Has Indigenous Third-World Arms Production been Effective in Reducing Third-World Arms Imports?", Third-World Military Expenditure and Arms Production, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 99–113, doi:10.1007/978-1-349-09658-9_6, ISBN   978-1-349-09660-2 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  196. Brennan, Jason (2012-04-29), "The Tragedy of the Commons", The Ethics of Voting, Princeton University Press, doi:10.23943/princeton/9780691154442.003.0011, ISBN   978-0-691-15444-2 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  197. Young, Kue (2012-08-29). "Indigenous Populations of North America, Australasia, and Circumpolar North". Oxford Bibliographies Online Datasets. doi:10.1093/obo/9780199756797-0039 . Retrieved 2021-05-25.
  198. Harvey, David (2011). "The future of the commons" (PDF). Radical History Review. 2011 (109): 101–107. doi:10.1215/01636545-2010-017.
  199. Benkler, Yochai (2016). "Peer production and cooperation". Handbook on the Economics of the Internet: 91–119. doi:10.4337/9780857939852.00012. ISBN   978-0-85793-985-2.
  200. Obokata, Tom (2006-01-01), "Chapter 4. Trafficking of Human Beings as a Human Rights Abuse: Obligations and Accountability of Non-State Actors", Trafficking of Human Beings from a Human Rights Perspective, Brill | Nijhoff, pp. 121–145, doi:10.1163/ej.9789004154056.i-247.30, ISBN   978-90-474-1106-2 , retrieved 2021-05-25
  201. Benkler, Yochai (2006). The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom . New Haven, Conn: Yale University Press. p.  3. ISBN   978-0-300-11056-2.
  202. Steven Johnson (September 21, 2012). "The Internet? We Built That". New York Times . Retrieved 2012-09-24. The Harvard legal scholar Yochai Benkler has called this phenomenon 'commons-based peer production'.
  203. "Introduction: Open Source Software and the Digital Commons", Incorporating the Digital Commons: Corporate Involvement in Free and Open Source Software, University of Westminster Press, pp. 1–32, 2020-02-26, doi: 10.16997/book39.a , ISBN   978-1-912656-42-4, S2CID   242428235
  204. Karnani, Aneel G. (2013). "Corporate Social Responsibility Does Not Avert the Tragedy of the Commons -- Case Study: Coca-Cola India". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2354022. hdl: 2027.42/100359 . ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   155003836.
  205. Sinden, Amy (2006). "The Tragedy of the Commons and the Myth of a Private Property Solution". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.895724. hdl: 20.500.12613/7454 . ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   154084058.
  206. Rowland, Wade (2009-09-01). "Corporate Social Responsibility and Garrett Hardin's Tragedy of the Commons as Myth and Reality". Journal of Corporate Citizenship. 2009 (35): 109–118. doi:10.9774/gleaf.4700.2009.au.00010 (inactive 2024-11-11). ISSN   1470-5001.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of November 2024 (link)
  207. Rajan, Sudhir Chella (September 2011). "Poor little rich countries: another look at the 'resource curse'". Environmental Politics. 20 (5): 617–632. Bibcode:2011EnvPo..20..617R. doi:10.1080/09644016.2011.608530. ISSN   0964-4016. S2CID   17155966.
  208. Shaxson, Nicholas (2007-10-22). "Oil, corruption and the resource curse". International Affairs. 83 (6): 1123–1140. doi:10.1111/j.1468-2346.2007.00677.x. ISSN   0020-5850. S2CID   41888272.
  209. Mildenberger, Matto (2019). "The Tragedy of the Tragedy of the Commons". Scientific American. Retrieved 19 May 2024.
  210. "Garrett Hardin". Southern Povery Law Center. Retrieved 19 May 2024.
  211. Rose, Carol (1986). "The Comedy of the Commons: Custom, Commerce, and Inherently Public Property". The University of Chicago Law Review. 53 (3): 711–781. doi:10.2307/1599583. ISSN   0041-9494. JSTOR   1599583.
  212. Rose, Carol M. (1986). "The Comedy of the Commons: Commerce, Custom, and Inherently Public Property". Faculty Scholarship Series, Yale Law School. Paper 1828.
  213. Rosenthal, Erika; Watson, Robert (April 2011). "Multilateral Efforts to Reduce Black Carbon Emissions: A Lifeline for the Warming Arctic?". Review of European Community & International Environmental Law. 20 (1): 3–10. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9388.2011.00705.x. ISSN   0962-8797.
  214. Richards, Garrett (2015-12-01). "Comedy of the Commons: Cheerful Options for Shared Resources in an Era of Climate Change". Alternatives . 41: 50.

Bibliography