Economy of the Soviet Union

Last updated

Economy of the Soviet Union
DneproGES 1947.JPG
The DniproHES hydro-electric power plant, one of the symbols of Soviet economic power, was completed in 1932
Currency Rouble (SUR) [1]
1 January–31 December (calendar year) [1]
Trade organisations
Comecon, ESCAP and others [1]
Statistics
GDP $820 billion in 1977
(nominal; 2nd)
$1.21 trillion in 1980
(nominal; 2nd)
$1.57 trillion in 1982
(nominal; 2nd)
$2.20 trillion in 1985
(nominal; 2nd)
$2.66 trillion in 1990
(PPP; 2nd) [2]
GDP rank2nd [2] [3]
GDP growth
4.7% (in 1977) 4.2% ( in 1980) 3.8% (in 1982) 3.5% (in 1985) 0.9% (in 1990)
GDP per capita
$6,577 in 1977
(nominal)
$7,568 in 1980
(nominal)
$7,943 in 1982
(nominal)
$8,896 in 1985
(nominal)
$9,931 in 1991
(GNP; 28th) [4]
GDP by sector
Agriculture: (20%)
Industry: (80%)
(1988 est.) [1]
14% (43rd) (in 1991) 3.9% (in 1984) [5]
Population below poverty line
1-3% of population (1980 est.)
12% of population (1991 est.)
0.290 (1980 est.)
0.275 (1989 est.) [6]
Labour force
152.3 million (3rd)
(1989 est.) [7]
Labour force by occupation
80% in industry and other non-agricultural sectors; 20% in agriculture (1989 est.) [1]
Unemployment1–2% (1990 est.) [1]
Main industries
Petroleum, steel, motor vehicles, aerospace, machinery, telecommunications, chemicals, heavy industries, electronics, food processing, lumber, mining and defense (1989 est.) [1]
External
Exports$124.7 billion (9th)
(1989 est.) [8]
Export goods
Petroleum and petroleum products, natural gas, metals, wood, machinery, agricultural products and a wide variety of manufactured goods
(1989 est.) [1]
Main export partners
Eastern Bloc 49%, European Community 14%, Cuba 5%, United States, Afghanistan
(1988 est.) [1]
Imports$114.7 billion (10th)
(1989 est.) [9]
Import goods
Grain and other agricultural products, machinery and equipment, steel products (including large-diameter pipe), consumer manufactures [1]
Main import partners
Eastern Bloc 54%, European Community 11%, Cuba, China, United States
(1988 est.) [1]
$55 billion (11th)
(1989 est.) [10]
$27.3 billion
(1988 est.) [11]
Public finances
Revenues$422 billion (5th)
(1990 est.) [12]
Expenses$510 billion (1989 est.) [1]
$53 million (2nd; capital expenditures) (1991 est.) [13]
Economic aid$147.6 billion (1954–1988) [1]

All values, unless otherwise stated, are in US dollars.

The economy of the Soviet Union was based on state ownership of the means of production, collective farming, and industrial manufacturing. An administrative-command system managed a distinctive form of central planning. The Soviet economy was characterized by state control of investment, prices, a dependence on natural resources, lack of consumer goods, little foreign trade, public ownership of industrial assets, macroeconomic stability, low unemployment and high job security. [14]

Contents

Beginning in 1930, the course of the economy of the Soviet Union was guided by a series of five-year plans. By the 1950s, the Soviet Union had rapidly evolved from a mainly agrarian society into a major industrial power. [15] Its transformative capacity meant communism consistently appealed to the intellectuals of developing countries in Asia. [16] Impressive growth rates during the first three five-year plans (1928–1940) are particularly notable given that this period is nearly congruent with the Great Depression. [17] During this period, the Soviet Union saw rapid industrial growth while other regions were suffering from crisis. [18] The White House National Security Council of the United States described the continuing growth as a "proven ability to carry backward countries speedily through the crisis of modernization and industrialization", and the impoverished base upon which the five-year plans sought to build meant that at the commencement of Operation Barbarossa in 1941 the country was still poor. [19] [20]

Even so, the Soviet Union had the second largest economy in the world from the end of World War II until the mid-1980s. A major strength of the Soviet economy was its enormous supply of oil and gas, which became much more valuable as exports after the world price of oil skyrocketed in the 1970s. As Daniel Yergin notes, the Soviet economy in its final decades was "heavily dependent on vast natural resources–oil and gas in particular". World oil prices collapsed in 1986, putting heavy pressure on the economy. [21] After Mikhail Gorbachev became the General Secretary of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union and came to power in 1985, he began a process of economic liberalization by dismantling the command economy and moving towards a mixed economy modeled after Lenin's New Economic Policy. At its dissolution at the end of 1991, the Soviet Union began a Russian Federation with a growing pile of $66 billion in external debt and with barely a few billion dollars in net gold and foreign exchange reserves. [22]

The complex demands of the modern economy somewhat constrained the central planners. Data fiddling became common practice among the bureaucracy by reporting fulfilled targets and quotas, thus entrenching the crisis. From the Stalin-era to the early Brezhnev-era, the Soviet economy grew slower than Japan and faster than the United States. GDP levels in 1950 (in billion 1990 dollars) were 510 (100%) in the Soviet Union, 161 (100%) in Japan and 1,456 (100%) in the United States. By 1965, the corresponding values were 1,011 (198%), 587 (365%) and 2,607 (179%). [23] The Soviet Union maintained itself as the world's second largest economy in both nominal and purchasing power parity values throughout the Cold War, until 1990 when Japan's economy exceeded $3 trillion in nominal value. [24]

The Soviet Union's relatively medium consumer sector accounted for just almost 60% of the country's GDP in 1990 while the industrial and agricultural sectors contributed 22% and 20% respectively in 1991. Agriculture was the predominant occupation in the Soviet Union before the massive industrialization under Soviet general secretary Joseph Stalin. The service sector was of low importance in the Soviet Union, with the majority of the labor force employed in the industrial sector. The labor force totaled 152.3 million people. Though its GDP crossed $1 trillion in the 1970s and $2 trillion in the 1980s, the effects of central planning were progressively distorted due to the growth of the black market informal second economy in the Soviet Union. [25]

Planning

Based on a system of state ownership, the Soviet economy was managed through Gosplan (the State Planning Commission), Gosbank (the State Bank) and the Gossnab (State Commission for Materials and Equipment Supply). Beginning in 1928, the economy was directed by a series of five-year plans, with a brief attempt at seven-year planning. For every enterprise, planning ministries (also known as the "fund holders" or fondoderzhateli) defined the mix of economic inputs (e.g. labor and raw materials), a schedule for completion, all wholesale prices and almost all retail prices. The planning process was based around material balances—balancing economic inputs with planned output targets for the planning period. From 1930 until the late 1950s, the range of mathematics used to assist economic decision-making was, for ideological reasons, extremely restricted. [26] On the whole, the plans were overoptimistic and plagued by falsified reporting. [27]

The industry was long concentrated after 1928 on the production of capital goods through metallurgy, machine manufacture, and chemical industry. In Soviet terminology, goods were known as capital.[ citation needed ] This emphasis was based on the perceived necessity for very fast industrialization and modernization of the Soviet Union. After the death of Joseph Stalin in 1953, consumer goods (group B goods) received somewhat more emphasis due to the efforts of Georgy Malenkov. However, when Nikita Khrushchev consolidated his power by sacking Malenkov, one of the accusations against him was that he permitted "theoretically incorrect and politically harmful opposition to the rate of development of heavy industry in favor of the rate of development of light and food industry". [28] Since 1955, the priorities were again given to capital goods, which was expressed in the decisions of the 20th Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union (CPSU) in 1956. [29]

Economist Naum Jasny says that while many of the official statistics were correctly reported:

The fact is that the most important official general indices of economic development – those of national income, industrial output, real incomes of wage-earners and peasants, labour productivity and production costs in industry – have, over long periods of time....nothing in common with reality. [30]

Most information in the Soviet economy flowed from the top down. There were several mechanisms in place for producers and consumers to provide input and information that would help in the drafting of economic plans (as detailed below), but the political climate was such that few people ever provided negative input or criticism of the plan and thus Soviet planners had very little reliable feedback that they could use to determine the success of their plans. This meant that economic planning was often done based on faulty or outdated information, particularly in sectors with large numbers of consumers. As a result, some goods tended to be underproduced and led to shortages while other goods were overproduced and accumulated in storage. Low-level managers often did not report such problems to their superiors, relying instead on each other for support. Some factories developed a system of barter and either exchanged or shared raw materials and parts without the knowledge of the authorities and outside the parameters of the economic plan.

Heavy industry was always the focus of the Soviet economy even in its later years. The fact that it received special attention from the planners, combined with the fact that industrial production was relatively easy to plan even without minute feedback, led to significant growth in that sector. The Soviet Union became one of the leading industrial nations of the world. Industrial production was disproportionately high in the Soviet Union compared to Western economies. By the 60s calorie consumption per person in the Soviet Union was at levels similar to the United States. However, the production of consumer goods was disproportionately low. Economic planners made little effort to determine the wishes of household consumers, resulting in severe shortages of many consumer goods. Whenever these consumer goods would become available on the market, consumers routinely had to stand in long lines (queues) to buy them. [31] A black market developed for goods such as cigarettes that were particularly sought after, but it constantly underproduced. People were developing unique social "networks of favors" between people having access to sought after goods (for example, working in particular shops or factories). [32]

Drafting the five-year plans

Leon Trotsky was among the earliest Soviet figures that supported economic planning and decentralization but opposed the Stalinist model. Leon Trotsky in exile.webp
Leon Trotsky was among the earliest Soviet figures that supported economic planning and decentralization but opposed the Stalinist model.

Under Joseph Stalin's close supervision, a complex system of planning arrangements had developed since the introduction of the first five-year plan in 1928. [35] Preceding this, Leon Trotsky had delivered a joint report to the April Plenum of the Central Committee in 1926 which proposed a program for national industrialisation and the replacement of annual plans with five-year plans. His proposals were rejected by the Central Committee majority which was controlled by the troika and derided by Stalin at the time. [36] Stalin's version of the five-year plan was implemented in 1928 and took effect until 1932. [37] According to historian Sheila Fitzpatrick, the scholarly consensus was that Stalin appropriated the position of the Left Opposition on such matters as industrialisation and collectivisation. [38]

Until the late 1980s and early 1990s, when economic reforms backed by Soviet leader Mikhail Gorbachev introduced significant changes in the traditional system (see perestroika), the allocation of resources was directed by a planning apparatus rather than through the interplay of market forces.

Time frame

From the Stalin era through the late 1980s, the five-year plan integrated short-range planning into a longer time frame. It delineated the chief thrust of the country's economic development and specified the way the economy could meet the desired goals of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union. Although the five-year plan was enacted into law, it contained a series of guidelines rather than a set of direct orders.

Periods covered by the five-year plans coincided with those covered by the gatherings of the CPSU Party Congress. At each CPSU Congress, the party leadership presented the targets for the next five-year plan, therefore each plan had the approval of the most authoritative body of the country's leading political institution.

Guidelines for the plan

The Central Committee of the CPSU and more specifically its Politburo set basic guidelines for planning. The Politburo determined the general direction of the economy via control figures (preliminary plan targets), major investment projects (capacity creation) and general economic policies. These guidelines were submitted as a report of the Central Committee to the Congress of the CPSU to be approved there. After the approval at the Congress, the list of priorities for the five-year plan was processed by the Council of Ministers, which constituted the government of the Soviet Union. The Council of Ministers was composed of industrial ministers, chairmen of various state committees and chairmen of agencies with ministerial status. This committee stood at the apex of the vast economic administration, including the state planning apparatus, the industrial ministries, the trusts (the intermediate level between the ministries and the enterprises) and finally the state enterprises. The Council of Ministers elaborated on Politburo plan targets and sent them to Gosplan, which gathered data on plan fulfillment. [39]

Gosplan

Combining the broad goals laid out by the Council of Ministers with data supplied by lower administrative levels regarding the current state of the economy, Gosplan worked out through trial and error a set of preliminary plan targets. Among more than twenty state committees, Gosplan headed the government's planning apparatus and was by far the most important agency in the economic administration. The task of planners was to balance resources and requirements to ensure that the necessary inputs were provided for the planned output. The planning apparatus alone was a vast organizational arrangement consisting of councils, commissions, governmental officials, specialists and so on charged with executing and monitoring economic policy.

The state planning agency was subdivided into its own industrial departments, such as coal, iron and machine building. It also had summary departments such as finance, dealing with issues that crossed functional boundaries. With the exception of a brief experiment with regional planning during the Khrushchev era in the 1950s, Soviet planning was done on a sectoral basis rather than on a regional basis. The departments of the state planning agency aided the agency's development of a full set of plan targets along with input requirements, a process involving bargaining between the ministries and their superiors. Economic ministries performed key roles in the Soviet organizational structure. When the planning goals had been established by Gosplan, economic ministries drafted plans within their jurisdictions and disseminated planning data to the subordinate enterprises. The planning data were sent downward through the planning hierarchy for progressively more detailed elaboration. The ministry received its control targets, which were then disaggregated by branches within the ministry, then by lower units, eventually until each enterprise received its own control figures (production targets). [40]

Enterprises were called upon to develop in the final period of state planning in the late 1980s and early 1990s (even though such participation was mostly limited to a rubber-stamping of prepared statements during huge pre-staged meetings). The enterprises' draft plans were then sent back up through the planning ministries for review. This process entailed intensive bargaining, with all parties seeking the target levels and input figures that best suited their interests.

After this bargaining process, Gosplan received the revised estimates and re-aggregated them as it saw fit. The redrafted plan was then sent to the Council of Ministers and the party's Politburo and Central Committee Secretariat for approval. The Council of Ministers submitted the plan to the Supreme Soviet of the Soviet Union and the Central Committee submitted the plan to the party congress, both for rubber stamp approval. By this time, the process had been completed and the plan became law.

The review, revision and approval of the five-year plan were followed by another downward flow of information, this time with the amended and final plans containing the specific targets for each sector of the economy. Implementation began at this point and was largely the responsibility of enterprise managers.

The national state budget was prepared by the Ministry of Finance of the Soviet Union by negotiating with its all-Union local organizations. If the state budget was accepted by the Soviet Union, it was then adopted. [41]

According to a number of scholars both inside and outside of USSR, it was specifically Soviet-type economic planning combined with political dogmatism which led to gradual degradation of Soviet economy and its collapse. [42] [43] [44] [45]

Agriculture

"Strengthen working discipline in collective farms", a Soviet propaganda poster issued in Uzbekistan, 1933 "Strengthen working discipline in collective farms" - Uzbek, Tashkent, 1933 (Mardjani).jpg
"Strengthen working discipline in collective farms", a Soviet propaganda poster issued in Uzbekistan, 1933

In the USSR, agriculture was organized into a system of collective farms (kolkhozes) and state farms (sovkhozes). These farms were collectivized distributed amongst the peasantry and yearly production quotas were set by administrators. Before Stalin, Soviet agriculture held its own. Data from the 1920s infers a positive supply response to increases in the terms of trade. Farmers increased grain sales to urban areas when the price of grain increased. [46] However, at the time, agricultural production was limited by technology, as the whole of Soviet Agriculture relied heavily on animal powered tilling. In the 1930s due to massive famines and animal die offs, the number of remaining animals doing farm work was reduced by half. [46] This indicated the dire need of additional production outputs, which administrators predicted could be supplied by mechanical harvesters. The planning of Soviet leadership emphasized a mechanical agricultural industry, whereby technology and ideology met to create a booming agricultural industry. [47] This way, the technological evolution of Soviet agricultural production could be linked to urban industry. [48] Yet in reality, Soviet planners were more invested in industry than farmers, and the Soviet agricultural industry suffered as a result. [49]

Leon Trotsky and the Opposition bloc had advocated a programme of industrialization which also proposed agricultural cooperatives and the formation of collective farms on a voluntary basis. [50] Several scholars have argued that the economic programme of Trotsky differed from the forced policy of collectivisation implemented by Stalin after 1928 due to the levels of brutality associated with its enforcement. [51] [52] [53]

Stalin's first Five year Plan (1929–1933) was a colossal failure. Soviet population declined after 1933, and would see modest growth until 1936. [54] The figures suggest a gap of about 15 million people between anticipated population and those that survived the five-year plan. [54] Systemic inefficiencies plagued Soviet agriculture, such as obsolete technology, waste of fuel resources, and depreciating capital stock. [55] These inefficiencies clogged the Soviet agricultural machine and reduced output. Additionally, climate greatly affected Soviet agricultural output. Many regions throughout the USSR had little rainfall, short growing seasons, low temperatures, and general extremes unsuitable for optimal agricultural production. [49] This was detrimental to agricultural output and prevented cost minimization. When harvests fell short of production quotas due to a sudden frost or long drought, Soviet output could not make up the difference. Consequently, when agriculture was not producing as promised, some peasants refused to work over fear of starvation. However, since Soviet farms were collectivized, no individual grievances could be tolerated for the societal system to succeed. As a result, peasants unwilling to join kolkhozy were forced off of their land, which was then redistributed to other peasants. [54]

Nikita Khrushchev and Joseph Stalin, 1936. Joseph Stalin and Nikita Khrushchev, 1936.jpg
Nikita Khrushchev and Joseph Stalin, 1936.

Following previous agricultural failures, Khrushchev abandoned Stalin's agricultural model. [49] He instead looked comparatively at American agriculture through Soviet observers. He noticed that American agriculture flourished due to its specialization and interdependence on other farmers for goods and services. Similarly, Soviet farms could specialize in the crop which was best suited for growing in their region, and surplus could be transported throughout the USSR to satisfy quotas and distribute to people who needed the food. Khrushchev himself tended to suggest his favorite crops such as corn for planters. [49] Paired with a need to proselytize mechanized agriculture to nearby countries, the Khrushchev administration began a campaign for an optimistic future of mechanized Soviet agriculture. [49] However, Khrushchev was not able to fulfill his promises, and this contributed to his rising unpopularity which culminated in his removal from power. [49]

Following Khrushchev's leadership, Soviet agriculture's legacy was defined by patchwork that attempted to fix the mistakes of the previous administrations. Crop harvests, tractors, fertilizer, and capital investment were all increasing since 1955. [49]   By 1965, the output of the Soviet worker was increasing, but still well below average for a developed country. [48] Problems such as a scarcity of educated workers, saturation of unskilled workers and jobs made obsolete by technology, and poorly trained and educated farmers brought costs up and drove production down. [48] These issues prevented the Soviet Union from producing enough food, as a lack of administration and management led to the mismanagement of farms and reduced worker productivity. From 1972 to 1986, the Soviet Union failed to produce more wheat than the Western European average. [55] This failure to produce resulted in forced Soviet imports of food. Between 1961 and 1985, Soviet food imports from foreign producers cost a total of nearly 240 billion dollars. [55] The root of this expense can be identified in the inefficiencies of the Soviet agricultural sector, such as the shortage of workers, lag in technology, or natural factors such as drought or frosts. Although the Soviet Union aimed to establish a mechanized agricultural giant, the shortcomings of Soviet agriculture put the sector behind other countries from the beginning. Soviet agriculture had the inability to meet basic consumer demands and expectations, requiring policy change culminating in the dissolution of the USSR in 1991. [55]

Foreign trade and currency

Largely self-sufficient, the Soviet Union traded little in comparison to its economic strength. However, trade with non-communist countries increased in the 1970s as the government sought to compensate gaps in domestic production with imports.

In general, fuels, metals and timber were exported, while consumer goods and sometimes grain were imported. In the 1980s, trade with the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON) member states accounted for about half the country's volume of trade.

The Soviet rouble was non-convertible after 1932 (when trade in gold-convertible chervonets, introduced by Lenin in the New Economic Policy years, was suspended) until the late 1980s. It was impossible (both for citizens and state-owned businesses) to freely buy or sell foreign currency even though the "exchange rate" was set and published regularly. Buying or selling foreign currency on a black market was a serious crime until the late 1980s. Individuals who were paid from abroad (for example writers whose books were published abroad) normally had to spend their currency in a foreign-currency-only chain of state-owned Beryozka ("Birch-tree") stores. Once a free conversion of currency was allowed, the exchange rate plummeted from its official values by almost a factor of 10.

Overall, the banking system was highly centralized and fully controlled by a single state-owned Gosbank, responsive to the fulfillment of the government's economic plans. Soviet banks furnished short-term credit to state-owned enterprises.

Forms of property

There were two basic forms of property in the Soviet Union: individual property and collective property. These differed greatly in their content and legal status. According to communist theory, capital (means of production) should not be individually owned, with certain negligible exceptions. In particular, after the end of a short period of the New Economic Policy and with collectivization completed, all industrial property and virtually all land were collective.

Land in rural areas was allotted for housing and some sustenance farming, and persons had certain rights to it, but it was not their property in full. In particular, in kolkhozes and sovkhozes there was a practice to rotate individual farming lots with collective lots. This resulted in situations where people would ameliorate, till and cultivate their lots carefully, adapting them to small-scale farming and in 5–7 years those lots would be swapped for kolkhoz ones, typically with exhausted soil due to intensive, large-scale agriculture [ citation needed ]. There was an extremely small number of remaining individual farmsteads ( khutors ; хутор), located in isolated rural areas in the Baltic states, Ukraine, Siberia and cossack lands.

Individual property

To distinguish "capitalist" and "socialist" types of property ownership further, two different forms of individual property were recognized: private property (частная собственность, chastnaya sobstvennost) and personal property (личная собственность, lichnaya sobstvennost). The former encompassed capital (means of production) while the latter described everything else in a person's possession.

Collective property

There were several forms of collective ownership, the most significant being state property, kolkhoz property and cooperative property. The most common forms of cooperative property were housing cooperatives (жилищные кооперативы) in urban areas, consumer cooperatives (потребительская кооперация, потребкооперация) and rural consumer societies (сельские потребительские общества, сельпо).

History

GDP per capita in the former USSR, 1922 to 1991 GDP per capita development of the Soviet Union.svg
GDP per capita in the former USSR, 1922 to 1991

See also History of the Soviet Union

Early development

Both the Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic and later the Soviet Union were countries in the process of industrialization. For both, this development occurred slowly and from a low initial starting-point. Because of World War I (1914–1918), the Russian Revolution of 1917 and the ensuing Russian Civil War (1917–1922), industrial production had only managed to barely recover its 1913 level by 1926. [56] By this time, about 18% of the population lived in non-rural areas, although only about 7.5% were employed in the non-agricultural sector. The remainder remained stuck in low-productivity agriculture. [57]

David A. Dyker sees the Soviet Union of circa 1930 as in some ways a typical developing country, characterized by low capital-investment and with most of its population residing in the countryside. Part of the reason[ citation needed ] for low investment-rates lay in the inability to acquire capital from abroad. This in turn, resulted from the repudiation of the debts of the Russian Empire by the Bolsheviks in 1918 [58] as well as from the worldwide financial troubles. Consequently, any kind of economic growth had to be financed by domestic savings. [57]

The economic problems in agriculture were further exacerbated by natural conditions, such as long cold winters across the country, droughts in the south and acidic soils in the north. However, according to Dyker, the Soviet economy did have "extremely good" potential in the area of raw materials and mineral extraction, for example in the oil fields in Transcaucasia, and this, along with a small but growing manufacturing base, helped the Soviet Union avoid any kind of balance of payments problems. [57]

New Economic Policy (1921–1929)

One of the several photographs intended to show the two major economic policy makers of the Soviet Union together, Vladimir Lenin (left) who created the NEP and Joseph Stalin (right) who created the command economy Lenin and stalin crop.jpg
One of the several photographs intended to show the two major economic policy makers of the Soviet Union together, Vladimir Lenin (left) who created the NEP and Joseph Stalin (right) who created the command economy

By early 1921, it became apparent to the Bolsheviks that forced requisitioning of grain had resulted in low agricultural production and widespread opposition. As a result, the decision was made by Lenin and the Politburo to try an alternative approach. [60] The so-called New Economic Policy (NEP) was approved at the 10th Congress of the Russian Communist Party (Bolsheviks). [61]

Everything except "the commanding heights", as Lenin put it, of the economy would be privatized. The commanding heights included foreign trade, heavy industry, communication and transport among others. [60] In practice this limited the private sector to artisan and agricultural production/trade. [62] The NEP encountered strong resistance within the Bolshevik party. Lenin had to persuade communist skeptics that "state capitalism" was a necessary step in achieving communism, while he himself harbored suspicions that the policy could be abused by private businessmen ("NEPmen"). [63]

As novelist Andrei Platonov, among others, noted, the improvements were immediate. Rationing cards and queues, which had become hallmarks of war communism, had disappeared. However, due to prolonged war, low harvests, and several natural disasters the Soviet economy was still in trouble, particularly its agricultural sector. In 1921, widespread famine broke out in the Volga-Ural region. The Soviet government changed its previous course and allowed international relief to come in from abroad, and established a special committee chaired by prominent communists and non-communists alike. Despite this, an estimated five million people died in the famine. [64]

Armenian Soviet Socialist Republic

The Soviet-era republic's centralized economy forbade private ownership of property with an income. Privately owned farms in Armenia were collectivized and put under the control of the state starting in the late 1920s, however this was frequently met with vigorous opposition by the peasantry. During the same period (1929–1936), Armenia's industrialization process was also launched by the government. The socialist economic system and socialist ownership of the means of production, which come in two forms: state property and cooperative and collective-farm property, form the basis of the republic's economy. The legislation authorizes small private ventures of individual peasants and craftsmen based on their own labor and forbids the exploitation of the labor of others, in addition to the socialist system of economy, which is the major type of economy in the Republic. The official economic plan sets and directs the Republic's economic course. By 1935, the gross product of agriculture was 132% higher than that of 1928, and the gross product of industry was 650% more than that of 1928. However, the 1930s economic revolution came at a high price: it destroyed the conventional peasant family and village institution and caused many people who lived in the remote countryside to relocate to cities. As private enterprise was essentially brought under government control, it came to an end. [65]

Stalinism

Starting in 1928, the five-year plans began building a heavy industrial base at once in an underdeveloped economy without waiting years for capital to accumulate through the expansion of light industry, and without reliance on external financing. The New Economic Policy was rapidly abandoned and replaced by Stalinism. The country now became industrialized at a hitherto unprecedented pace, surpassing Germany's pace of industrialization in the 19th century and Japan's earlier in the 20th century.

After the reconstruction of the economy in the wake of the destruction caused by the Russian Civil War was completed and after the initial plans of further industrialization were fulfilled, the explosive growth slowed down until the period of Brezhnev stagnation in the 1970s and 1980s.

Led by the creation of NAMI and by the GAZ copy of the Ford Model A in 1929, [66] [67] [ circular reference ] industrialization came with the extension of medical services, which improved labor productivity. Campaigns were carried out against typhus, cholera and malaria; the number of physicians increased as rapidly as facilities and training would permit; and death and infant mortality rates steadily decreased.

In 1947 politburo announced a monetary reform (1947) that basically intended to confiscate "excessive" amount of money in order to weaken rampant illegal trade (which was banned at the time) and fill up budget at cost of people.

Ration stamps in Soviet Union were abolished in December 1947, six months after rationing ended in the US, and two years before France. Soviet post-war famine of 1946–1947 was still ravaging the country.

1930–1970

The State Quality Mark of the Soviet Union, introduced in 1967, was used to certify that goods met quality standards and to improve the efficiency of production Znak kachestva.svg
The State Quality Mark of the Soviet Union, introduced in 1967, was used to certify that goods met quality standards and to improve the efficiency of production

As weighed growth rates, economic planning performed very well during the early and mid-1930s, World War II-era mobilization, and for the first two decades of the postwar era. The Soviet Union became the world's leading producer of oil, coal, iron ore and cement; manganese, gold, natural gas and other minerals were also of major importance. However, information about the Soviet famine of 1932–1933 was suppressed by the Soviet authorities until perestroika.

To some estimations, in 1933 workers' real earnings sank on more than 11.4% from 1926 level, [68] though it needs an adjustment due to elimination of unemployment and perks at work (such as inexpensive meals). [69] Common and political prisoners in labor camps were forced to do unpaid labor and communists and Komsomol members were frequently "mobilized" for various construction projects. The German invasion of World War II inflicted punishing blows to the economy of the Soviet Union, with Soviet GDP falling 34% between 1940 and 1942. [70] Industrial output did not recover to its 1940 level for almost a decade. [20]

In 1961, a new redenominated Soviet rouble was issued with an exchange rate of £1 = Rbl 1. The rouble maintained exchange parity with sterling until the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991. After a new leadership, headed by Leonid Brezhnev, had come to power, attempts were made to revitalize the economy through economic reform. Starting in 1965, enterprises and organizations were made to rely on economic methods of profitable production, rather than follow orders from the state administration. By 1970, the Soviet economy had reached its zenith and was estimated at 60 percent of the size of the United States [71] in terms of the estimated commodities (like steel and coal). In 1989, the official GDP of the Soviet Union was $2,500 billion [72] while the GDP of the United States was $4,862 billion [73] with per capita income figures as $8,700 and $19,800 respectively.

The USSR was the first major non-Western country to close the developmental gap that had existed with the West since the 16th century. [74] :52 In the period 1930 to 1960s, the USSR successfully implemented catch-up development. [74] :52

1970–1990

After 1976, the USSR stopped narrowing the developmental gap with the West, and the gap further widened beginning in 1990. [74] :52

The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1972 in retail prices was about 118 billion roubles ($530 billion). [75] The Era of Stagnation in the mid-1970s was triggered by the Nixon Shock and aggravated by the war in Afghanistan in 1979 and led to a period of economic standstill between 1979 and 1985. Soviet military buildup at the expense of domestic development kept the Soviet Union's GDP at the same level during the first half of the 1980s. [76] The Soviet planned economy was not structured to respond adequately to the demands of the complex modern economy it had helped to forge. The massive quantities of goods produced often did not meet the needs or tastes of consumers. [77]

The volume of decisions facing planners in Moscow became overwhelming. The cumbersome procedures for bureaucratic administration foreclosed the free communication and flexible response required at the enterprise level for dealing with worker alienation, innovation, customers, and suppliers. During 1975–1985, data fiddling became common practice among bureaucracy to report satisfied targets and quotas thus entrenching the crisis. At the same time, the effects of the central planning were progressively distorted due to the rapid growth of the second economy in the Soviet Union. [25]

Soviet national income 1928-1987 growth in % based on estimates of the official statistical agency of the Soviet Union, the CIA and revised estimates by Grigorii Khanin Graph of Soviet National Income Growth.png
Soviet national income 1928–1987 growth in % based on estimates of the official statistical agency of the Soviet Union, the CIA and revised estimates by Grigorii Khanin

While all modernized economies were rapidly moving to computerization after 1965, the Soviet Union fell further and further behind. Even though Moscow decided to copy the IBM 360 of 1965, it had enormous difficulties in manufacturing the necessary chips reliably and in quantity, in programming workable and efficient programs, in coordinating entirely separate operations, and in providing support to computer users. [78] [79] [80]

One of the greatest strengths of Soviet economy was its vast supplies of oil and gas; world oil prices quadrupled in the 1973–1974 and rose again in 1979–1981, making the energy sector the chief driver of the Soviet economy, and was used to cover multiple weaknesses. At one point, Soviet Premier Alexei Kosygin told the head of oil and gas production that "things are bad with bread. Give me 3 million tons [of oil] over the plan". [81]

In 2007, economist and former Prime Minister Yegor Gaidar wrote the following about looking back to these three decades:

The hard currency from oil exports stopped the growing food supply crisis, increased the import of equipment and consumer goods, ensured a financial base for the arms race and the achievement of nuclear parity with the United States, and permitted the realization of such risky foreign-policy actions as the war in Afghanistan. [82]

Awareness of the growing crisis arose initially within the KGB which with its extensive network of informants in every region and institution had its finger on the pulse of the nation. Yuri Andropov, director of the KGB, created a secret department during the 1970s within the KGB devoted to economic analysis and when he succeeded Brezhnev in 1982 sounded the alarm forcefully to the Soviet leadership. However, Andropov's remedy of increased discipline proved ineffective. It was only when Andropov's protege Gorbachev assumed power that a determined, but ultimately unsuccessful, assault on the economic crisis was undertaken. [83]

The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1990 in retail prices was about 459 billion roubles ($2.1 trillion). [84] According to CIA estimates, by 1989 the size of the Soviet economy was roughly half that in the United States. [11]

Sector (distribution of Soviet workforce)19401965197019791984
Primary (agriculture and forestry)54%31%25%21%20%
Secondary (including construction, transport and communication)28%44%46%48%47%
Tertiary (including trade, finance, health, education, science and administration)18%25%29%31%33%
Total100%100%100%100%100%

Comparisons with other countries

GDP per capita (1990 Int$) comparison involving the area of Russia/USSR, United States, and Western Europe from 1820 to 1990 [85]
Russia/USSRUnited StatesWestern EuropeRussia/USSR as a % of United StatesRussia/USSR as a % of Western Europe
18206891,2571,2325556
18709432,4451,9743948
19131,4885,3013,4732843
19502,8349,5614,5943062
19736,05816,68911,5343653
19909,93123,21415,9883573
Evolution of GNP in comparison with European powers
(in millions of dollars of 1960)
Country18901900191319251938
Russia/Soviet Union21,18032,00052,42032,60075,964
Germany26,45435,80049,76045,00277,178
United Kingdom29,44136,27344,07443,70056,102
France19,75823,50027,40136,26239,284
Comparison between the economies of the Soviet Union and the United States (1989) according to 1990 CIA World Factbook data [11]
Soviet UnionUnited States
GDP (GNP) (1989; millions $)2,659,5005,233,300
Population (July 1990)290,938,469250,410,000
GDP per capita (GNP) ($)9,93121,082
Labor force (1989)152,300,000125,557,000

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Perestroika</span> Soviet political reform movement

Perestroika was a political reform movement within the Communist Party of the Soviet Union (CPSU) during the late 1980s widely associated with CPSU general secretary Mikhail Gorbachev and his glasnost policy reform. The literal meaning of perestroika is "restructuring", referring to the restructuring of the political and economic systems of the Soviet Union, in an attempt to end the Era of Stagnation.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Leonid Brezhnev</span> Leader of the Soviet Union from 1964 to 1982

Leonid Ilyich Brezhnev was a Soviet politician who served as General Secretary of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union from 1964 until his death in 1982, and Chairman of the Presidium of the Supreme Soviet from 1960 to 1964 and again from 1977 to 1982. His 18-year term as General Secretary was second only to Joseph Stalin's in duration. To this day, the value of Brezhnev's tenure as General Secretary remains debated by historians.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Five-year plans of the Soviet Union</span> Series of nation-wide centralized economic plans in the Soviet Union

The five-year plans for the development of the national economy of the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) consisted of a series of nationwide centralized economic plans in the Soviet Union, beginning in the late 1920s. The Soviet state planning committee Gosplan developed these plans based on the theory of the productive forces that formed part of the ideology of the Communist Party for development of the Soviet economy. Fulfilling the current plan became the watchword of Soviet bureaucracy.

In the mid-1980s, Communist Czechoslovakia was prosperous by the standards of the Eastern Bloc, and did well in comparison to many richer western countries. Consumption of some goods like meat, eggs and bread products was even higher than the average countries in Western Europe, and the population enjoyed high macroeconomic stability and low social friction. Inhabitants of Czechoslovakia enjoyed a standard of living generally higher than that found in most other East European countries. Heavily dependent on foreign trade, the country nevertheless had one of the Eastern Bloc's smallest international debts to non-socialist countries.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economy of East Germany</span>

The economy of the German Democratic Republic was a command economy following the model of the Soviet Union based on the principles of Marxism-Leninism. Sharing many characteristics with fellow COMECON member states — the East German economy stood in start contrast to the market and mixed economies of Western Europe, including West Germany. The state established production targets, set prices, and also allocated resources, codifying these decisions in comprehensive plans. The means of production were almost entirely state-owned. The GDR had an above-average standard of living compared to other Eastern Bloc countries or the Soviet Union, and enjoyed favorable duty and tariff terms with the West German market; in 1989, it was estimated that 50 to 60% of its trade was with Western countries. However by the mid-1980s its economy had reached a state of stagnation, contributing to the process of German reunification.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Alexei Kosygin</span> Soviet politician (1904–1980)

Alexei Nikolayevich Kosygin was a Soviet statesman during the Cold War. He served as the Premier of the Soviet Union from 1964 to 1980 and was one of the most influential Soviet policymakers in the mid-1960s along with General Secretary Leonid Brezhnev.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Era of Stagnation</span> 1964–1985 period of the Soviet Union

The "Era of Stagnation" is a term coined by Mikhail Gorbachev in order to describe the negative way in which he viewed the economic, political, and social policies of the Soviet Union that began during the rule of Leonid Brezhnev (1964–1982) and continued under Yuri Andropov (1982–1984) and Konstantin Chernenko (1984–1985). It is sometimes called the "Brezhnevian Stagnation" in English.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Consumer goods in the Soviet Union</span>

Consumer goods in the Soviet Union were usually produced by a two-category industry. Group A was "heavy industry", which included all goods that serve as an input required for the production of some other, final good. Group B was "consumer goods", final goods used for consumption, which included food, clothing and shoes, housing, and such heavy-industry products as appliances and fuels that are used by individual consumers. From the early days of the Stalin era, Group A received top priority in economic planning and allocation so as to industrialize the Soviet Union from its previous agricultural economy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Agriculture in the Soviet Union</span> Overview of agriculture in the Soviet Union

Agriculture in the Soviet Union was mostly collectivized, with some limited cultivation of private plots. It is often viewed as one of the more inefficient sectors of the economy of the Soviet Union. A number of food taxes were introduced in the early Soviet period despite the Decree on Land that immediately followed the October Revolution. The forced collectivization and class war against "kulaks" under Stalinism greatly disrupted farm output in the 1920s and 1930s, contributing to the Soviet famine of 1932–33. A system of state and collective farms, known as sovkhozes and kolkhozes, respectively, placed the rural population in a system intended to be unprecedentedly productive and fair but which turned out to be chronically inefficient and lacking in fairness. Under the administrations of Nikita Khrushchev, Leonid Brezhnev, and Mikhail Gorbachev, many reforms were enacted as attempts to defray the inefficiencies of the Stalinist agricultural system. However, Marxist–Leninist ideology did not allow for any substantial amount of market mechanism to coexist alongside central planning, so the private plot fraction of Soviet agriculture, which was its most productive, remained confined to a limited role. Throughout its later decades the Soviet Union never stopped using substantial portions of the precious metals mined each year in Siberia to pay for grain imports, which has been taken by various authors as an economic indicator showing that the country's agriculture was never as successful as it ought to have been. The real numbers, however, were treated as state secrets at the time, so accurate analysis of the sector's performance was limited outside the USSR and nearly impossible to assemble within its borders. However, Soviet citizens as consumers were familiar with the fact that foods, especially meats, were often noticeably scarce, to the point that not lack of money so much as lack of things to buy with it was the limiting factor in their standard of living.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">First five-year plan</span> Economic policy of the Soviet Union from 1928 to 1932

The first five-year plan of the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) was a list of economic goals, implemented by Communist Party General Secretary Joseph Stalin, based on his policy of socialism in one country. Leon Trotsky had delivered a joint report to the April Plenum of the Central Committee in 1926 which proposed a program for national industrialisation and the replacement of annual plans with five-year plans. His proposals were rejected by the Central Committee majority which was controlled by the troika and derided by Stalin at the time. Stalin's version of the five-year plan was implemented in 1928 and took effect until 1932.

Economic planning is a resource allocation mechanism based on a computational procedure for solving a constrained maximization problem with an iterative process for obtaining its solution. Planning is a mechanism for the allocation of resources between and within organizations contrasted with the market mechanism. As an allocation mechanism for socialism, economic planning replaces factor markets with a procedure for direct allocations of resources within an interconnected group of socially owned organizations which together comprise the productive apparatus of the economy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Industrialization in the Soviet Union</span>

Industrialization in the Soviet Union was a process of accelerated building-up of the industrial potential of the Soviet Union to reduce the economy's lag behind the developed capitalist states, which was carried out from May 1929 to June 1941.

After the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991 and the end of its centrally-planned economy, the Russian Federation succeeded it under president Boris Yeltsin. The Russian government used policies of shock therapy to liberalize the economy as part of the transition to a market economy, causing a sustained economic recession. GDP per capita levels returned to their 1991 levels by the mid-2000s. The economy of Russia is much more stable today than in the early 1990s, but inflation still remains an issue. Historically and currently, the Russian economy has differed sharply from major developed economies because of its weak legal system, underdevelopment of modern economic activities, technological backwardness, and lower living standards.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1965 Soviet economic reform</span> Attempt to introduce indicative planning, profits and sales to Soviet firms

The 1965 Soviet economic reform, sometimes called the Kosygin reform or Liberman reform, was a set of planned changes in the economy of the USSR. A centerpiece of these changes was the introduction of profitability and sales as the two key indicators of enterprise success. Some of an enterprise's profits would go to three funds, used to reward workers and expand operations; most would go to the central budget.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">History of the Soviet Union</span> Overview of history in the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics

The history of Soviet Russia and the Soviet Union (USSR) reflects a period of change for both Russia and the world. Though the terms "Soviet Russia" and "Soviet Union" often are synonymous in everyday speech, when referring to the foundations of the Soviet Union, "Soviet Russia" often specifically refers to brief period between the October Revolution of 1917 and the creation of the Soviet Union in 1922.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">New Economic Policy</span> 1921–28 Soviet economic policy theorized by Lenin

The New Economic Policy (NEP) was an economic policy of the Soviet Union proposed by Vladimir Lenin in 1921 as a temporary expedient. Lenin characterized the NEP in 1922 as an economic system that would include "a free market and capitalism, both subject to state control", while socialized state enterprises would operate on "a profit basis".

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Gosplan</span> Soviet government agency responsible for economic planning

The State Planning Committee, commonly known as Gosplan , was the agency responsible for central economic planning in the Soviet Union. Established in 1921 and remaining in existence until the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991, Gosplan had as its main task the creation and administration of a series of five-year plans governing the economy of the USSR.

Soviet-type economic planning (STP) is the specific model of centralized planning employed by Marxist–Leninist socialist states modeled on the economy of the Soviet Union (USSR).

The Eighth Five-Year Plan of the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) was a set of production goals and guidelines for administering the economy from 1966 to 1970—part of a series of such plans used by the USSR from 1928 until its dissolution. "Directives" for the plan involved set high goals for industrial production, especially in vehicles and appliances. These directives for the Eighth Five-Year Plan was approved by the Central Committee of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union and by the 23rd Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union but no final version was apparently ever ratified by the Supreme Soviet of the Soviet Union. Nevertheless, some of the changes envisioned were made.

The Soviet grain procurement crisis of 1928, sometimes referred to as "the crisis of NEP," was a pivotal economic event which took place in the Soviet Union beginning in January 1928 during which the quantities of wheat, rye, and other cereal crops made available for purchase by the state fell to levels regarded by planners as inadequate to support the needs of the country's urban population. Failure of the state to make successful use of the price system to generate sufficient grain sales was met with a regimen of increasingly harsh administrative sanctions against the Soviet peasantry. The state of national emergency which followed led to the termination of the New Economic Policy and spurred a move towards the collectivization of agriculture in 1929.

References

  1. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 "Soviet Union Economy 1991". CIA Factbook . 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  2. 1 2 "GDP – Million 1990". CIA Factbook . 1991. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  3. "GDP – Million 1991". CIA Factbook . KayLee. 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  4. "GDP Per Capita 1990". CIA Factbook . 1991. Retrieved 16 January 2017.
  5. "Inflation Rate % 1991". CIA Factbook . 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  6. Alexeev, Michael V. "Income Distribution in the USSR in the 1980s" (PDF). Review of Income and Wealth (1993). Indiana University. Retrieved 16 April 2017.
  7. "Labor Force 1991". CIA Factbook . 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  8. "Exports Million 1991". CIA Factbook . 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  9. "Imports Million 1991". CIA Factbook . 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  10. "Budget External Debt Million 1991". CIA Factbook . 1992. Archived from the original on 1 November 2012. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  11. 1 2 3 "1990 CIA World Factbook". Central Intelligence Agency. Archived from the original on 27 April 2011. Retrieved 23 July 2010.
  12. "Budget Revenues Million Million 1991". CIA Factbook . 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  13. "Budget Expenditures Million 1991", CIA Factbook , 1992, archived from the original on 1 November 2012, retrieved 12 June 2010
  14. Hanson, Philip (2003). The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Economy (Routledge). pp. 1–8.
  15. Davies 1998, p.  1, 3.
  16. Peck 2006 , p.  p. 47.
    One notable person in this regard was Nehru, "who visited the Soviet Union in the late 1920s and was deeply impressed by Soviet industrial progress." See Bradley 2010 , pp. 475–476.
  17. Allen 2003, p.  153.
  18. Baten, Jörg (2016). A History of the Global Economy. From 1500 to the Present. Cambridge University Press. pp. 62–63. ISBN   9781107507180.
  19. Harrison 1996, p.  123.
  20. 1 2 Davies 1998, p.  2.
  21. Daniel Yergin, The Quest: Energy, Security, and the Remaking of the Modern World (2011); quotes on pp 23, 24.
  22. Boughton 2012 , p. 288.
  23. Angus Maddison, The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective (2001) pp. 274, 275, 298.
  24. "Japan's IMF nominal GDP Data 1987 to 1989 (October 2014)".
  25. 1 2 Vladimir G. Treml and Michael V. Alexeev, "THE SECOND ECONOMY AND THE DESTABILIZING EFFECT OF ITS GROWTH ON THE STATE ECONOMY IN THE SOVIET UNION: 1965–1989", BERKELEY-DUKE OCCASIONAL PAPERS ON THE SECOND ECONOMY IN THE USSR, Paper No. 36, December 1993
  26. Smolinski 1973 , pp. 1189–90: "The mathematical sophistication of the tools actually employed was limited to those that had been used in Das Kapital: the four arithmetical operations, percentages, and arithmetic (but not geometric) mean."
  27. Holland Hunter, "The Overambitious First Soviet Five-Year Plan." Slavic Review 32.2 (1973): 237-257.
  28. "Георгий Маленков. 50 лет со дня отставки", Radio Liberty
  29. Пыжиков А. В. Хрущевская "Оттепель" : 1953—1964, Olma-Press, 2002 ISBN   978-5224033560
  30. Naum Jasny, "Some Thoughts on Soviet Statistics: An Evaluation," International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs) 35#1 (1959), pp. 53-60, online
  31. Revinskaya, Elena; RIR (16 October 2013). "A look at the old ration system in Russia". www.rbth.com. Retrieved 21 March 2019.
  32. "The Importance of Blats in Soviet Everyday Life | Socialist and Post-Socialist Cities" . Retrieved 21 March 2019.
  33. Twiss, Thomas M. (8 May 2014). Trotsky and the Problem of Soviet Bureaucracy. BRILL. pp. 88–113. ISBN   978-90-04-26953-8.
  34. Van Ree, Erik (1998). "Socialism in One Country: A Reassessment". Studies in East European Thought. 50 (2): 77–117. ISSN   0925-9392.
  35. Nick Shepley, Stalin, the Five Year Plans and the Gulags: Slavery and Terror 1929-53 (2015).
  36. Rogovin, Vadim Zakharovich (2021). Was There an Alternative? Trotskyism: a Look Back Through the Years. Mehring Books. p. 358. ISBN   978-1-893638-97-6.
  37. "The First Five Year Plan, 1928–1932". Special Collections & Archives. 7 October 2015. Retrieved 23 February 2019.
  38. Fitzpatrick, Sheila (22 April 2010). "The Old Man". London Review of Books. 32 (08). ISSN   0260-9592.
  39. R.W. Davies and Oleg Khlevnyuk, "Gosplan." in E. A. Rees, ed., Decision-making in the Stalinist Command Economy, 1932–37 (1997). 32-66.
  40. Michael Ellman, Socialist planning (Cambridge UP, 2014).
  41. the IMF (1991). A Study of the Soviet economy. Vol. 1. International Monetary Fund (IMF). p. 287. ISBN   978-92-64-13468-3.
  42. Dembinski, Pawel (1991). The Logic of Planned Economy: The Seeds of the Collapse. Clarendon Press. ISBN   978-0198286868.
  43. Ellman, Michael (1973). Planning Problems in the USSR: The Contribution of Mathematical Economics to their Solution 1960-1971. CUP Archive. ISBN   978-0521202497.
  44. "Optimizing things in the USSR · Chris Said". chris-said.io. Retrieved 15 November 2020.
  45. "Николай Петрович Шмелёв (Nikolay Shmelyov) "Авансы и долги (Avansy i dolgi)" ("Credits and debts"), Новый мир (Novyi Mir) – 1987. - № 6". echelon.pl. Retrieved 15 November 2020.
  46. 1 2 Antel, John; Gregory, Paul (1994). "Agricultural Surplus Models and Peasant Behavior: Soviet Agriculture in the 1920s". Economic Development and Cultural Change. 42 (2): 375–386. doi:10.1086/452085. ISSN   0013-0079. JSTOR   1154447. S2CID   153635813.
  47. Dekel-Chen, Jonathan (2020). "Putting Agricultural History to Work: Global Action Today from a Communal Past". Agricultural History. 94 (4): 512–544. doi:10.3098/ah.2020.094.4.512. ISSN   0002-1482. JSTOR   10.3098/ah.2020.094.4.512. S2CID   229207917.
  48. 1 2 3 Clayton, Elizabeth (September 1980). "Productivity in Soviet Agriculture". Slavic Review. 39 (3): 446–458. doi:10.2307/2497164. ISSN   0037-6779. JSTOR   2497164. S2CID   163496553.
  49. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 HALE-DORRELL, AARON (2015). "The Soviet Union, the United States, and Industrial Agriculture". Journal of World History. 26 (2): 295–324. ISSN   1045-6007. JSTOR   43901754.
  50. Kemp, Tom (14 January 2014). Industrialisation in the Non-Western World. Routledge. pp. 1–150. ISBN   978-1-317-90133-4.
  51. Mandel, Ernest (1995). Trotsky as alternative. London: Verso Books. p. 59. ISBN   978-1859840856.
  52. Daniels, Robert V. (1 October 2008). The Rise and Fall of Communism in Russia. Yale University Press. p. 195. ISBN   978-0-300-13493-3.
  53. Rubenstein, Joshua (2011). Leon Trotsky : a revolutionary's life. New Haven : Yale University Press. p. 161. ISBN   978-0-300-13724-8.
  54. 1 2 3 Hunter, Holland (1988). "Soviet Agriculture with and without Collectivization, 1928-1940". Slavic Review. 47 (2): 203–216. doi:10.2307/2498462. ISSN   0037-6779. JSTOR   2498462. S2CID   163882472.
  55. 1 2 3 4 Clairmonte, Frederick F. (1989). "Rise and Fall of Soviet Agriculture". Economic and Political Weekly. 24 (11): 555–560. ISSN   0012-9976. JSTOR   4394526.
  56. Dyker 1992, p. 2.
  57. 1 2 3 Dyker, David A. (1992). Restructuring the Soviet Economy. Routledge (published 2002). p. 3. ISBN   9781134917464 . Retrieved 18 October 2015. Repudiation of the international debts of the tsarist regime, coupled with the difficult economic conditions of the post-Wall Street crash period, ensured that any increase in the rate of accumulation would have to be internally financed. [...] In some ways, then, the Soviet Union c. 1930 was a typical developing country, with a relatively low level of accumulation and substantial surplus agricultural population. But she could not count on large-scale capital transfer from abroad – for better or worse.
  58. Rempel, Richard A.; Haslam, Beryl, eds. (2000). Uncertain Paths to Freedom: Russia and China, 1919–22. Collected papers of Bertrand Russell. Vol. 15. Psychology Press. p. 529. ISBN   9780415094115 . Retrieved 18 October 2015. French creditors were owed forty-three percent of the total Russian debt repudiated by the Bolsheviks on 28 January 1918.
  59. Lenin and Stalin in Gorki (close up)
  60. 1 2 Moss 2005, p.  228.
  61. Hosking, Geoffrey A. (1993). The First Socialist Society: A History of the Soviet Union from Within. Harvard University Press. p. 119. ISBN   978-0-674-30443-7 . Retrieved 24 March 2022.
  62. Carr, E.H. and Davies, R.W, (1988), Foundations of a Planned Economy, Vol. 1
  63. Moss 2005, p.  227.
  64. Hosking 1993, p. 120.
  65. "Armenian Attitudes Toward Work and the Soviet Legacy". 18 April 2022.
  66. G.N. Georgano Cars: Early and Vintage, 1886–1930. (London: Grange-Universal, 1985)
  67. Wikipedia, GAZ.
  68. Nove, Alec (1969), An Economic History of the U.S.S.R., IICA, p. 206
  69. Nove 1969 , p. 207
  70. Harrison 1996, p.  p. 124.
  71. "A Comparison of the US and Soviet Economies: Evaluating the Performance of the Soviet System" (PDF). foia.cia.gov. October 1985. Archived from the original (PDF) on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 7 April 2015.
  72. "Soviet Union Economy - 1989".
  73. "United States Economy - 1989"
  74. 1 2 3 Gnerre, Orazio Maria (2023). "Strengthening of the Sino-Russian Partnership". China and Eurasian powers in a Multipolar World Order 2.0: Security, Diplomacy, Economy and Cyberspace. Mher Sahakyan. New York: Routledge. ISBN   978-1-003-35258-7. OCLC   1353290533.
  75. Manufactured goods sector was worth 118 billion roubles in 1972
  76. "The Economic Impact of Soviet Military Spending" (PDF). www.cia.gov. April 1975. p. 2. Archived from the original (PDF) on 20 September 2016. Retrieved 9 December 2018.
  77. Shane, Scott (1994). "What Price Socialism? An Economy Without Information". Dismantling Utopia: How Information Ended the Soviet Union. Chicago: Ivan R. Dee. pp. 75 to 98. ISBN   978-1-56663-048-1. It was not the gas pedal but the steering wheel that was failing
  78. James W. Cortada, "Public Policies and the Development of National Computer Industries in Britain, France, and the Soviet Union, 1940—80." Journal of Contemporary History (2009) 44#3 pp: 493–512, especially page 509-10.
  79. Frank Cain, "Computers and the Cold War: United States restrictions on the export of computers to the Soviet Union and Communist China." Journal of Contemporary History (2005) 40#1 pp: 131–147. in JSTOR
  80. Parrott, Bruce (1985). Trade, Technology, and Soviet-American Relations. Indiana UP. pp. 10–12. ISBN   978-0253360250.
  81. Yergin, The Quest (2011) p 23
  82. Gaidar, Yegor (2007). Collapse of an Empire: Lessons for Modern Russia. Brookings Institution Press. p. 102. ISBN   978-0815731153.
  83. Shane, Scott (1994). "The KGB, Father of Perestroika". Dismantling Utopia: How Information Ended the Soviet Union. Chicago: Ivan R. Dee. pp. 59, 60, 99 to 120. ISBN   978-1-56663-048-1. When he spoke to the leadership circle he said the country was faced with a question of survival
  84. United States. Congress. Joint Economic Committee; John Pearce Hardt (1993). The Former Soviet Union in Transition. M.E. Sharpe. p. 495. ISBN   978-1-56324-318-9.
  85. Maddison, Angus (2006). The World Economy (PDF). Paris, France: Development Centre of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). p. 185. ISBN   978-92-64-02261-4.

Works cited

Further reading

In Russian

  • Kara-Murza, Sergey (2004). Soviet Civilization: From 1917 to the Great Victory (in Russian) Сергей Кара-Мурза. Советская цивилизация. От начала до Великой Победы. ISBN   5-699-07590-9.
  • Kara-Murza, Sergey (2004). Soviet Civilization: From the Great Victory Till Our Time (in Russian). Сергей Кара-Мурза. Советская цивилизация. От Великой Победы до наших дней. ISBN   5-699-07591-7.