Luxury goods

Last updated
Wine and foie gras Foie gras with sauternes.jpg
Wine and foie gras

In economics, a luxury good (or upmarket good) is a good for which demand increases more than what is proportional as income rises, so that expenditures on the good become a more significant proportion of overall spending. Luxury goods are in contrast to necessity goods, where demand increases proportionally less than income. [1] Luxury goods is often used synonymously with superior goods.

Contents

Definition and etymology

The word "luxury" derives from the Latin verb luxor meaning to overextend or strain. From this, the noun luxuria and verb luxurio developed, "indicating immoderate growth, swelling, ... in persons and animals, willful or unruly behavior, disregard for moral restraints, and licensciousness", and the term has had negative connotations for most of its long history. [2] One definition in the OED is a "thing desirable but not necessary". A luxury good can be identified by comparing the demand for the good at one point in time against the demand for the good at a different time, at a different income level. When personal income increases, demand for luxury goods increases even more than income does.

Conversely, when personal income decreases, demand for luxury goods drops even more than income does. [3] For example, if income rises 1%, and the demand for a product rises 2%, then the product is a luxury good. This contrasts with necessity goods, or basic goods, for which demand stays the same or decreases only slightly as income decreases. [3]

Scope of the term

With increasing accessibility to luxury goods, [4] new product categories have been created within the luxury market, called "accessible luxury" or "mass luxury". These are meant specifically for the middle class, sometimes called the "aspiring class" in this context. Because luxury has diffused into the masses, defining the word has become more difficult. [5]

Whereas luxury often refers to certain types of products, luxury is not restricted to physical goods; services can also be luxury. Likewise, from the consumer perspective, luxury is an experience defined as "hedonic escapism". [6]

Confusion with normal goods

"Superior goods" is the gradable antonym of "inferior good". If the quantity of an item demanded increases with income, but not by enough to increase the share of the budget spent on it, then it is only a normal good and is not a superior good. Consumption of all normal goods increases as income increases. For example, if income increases by 50%, then consumption will increase (maybe by only 1%, maybe by 40%, maybe by 70%). A superior good is a normal good for which the proportional consumption increase exceeds the proportional income increase. So, if income increases by 50%, then consumption of a superior good will increase by more than 50% (maybe 51%, maybe 70%).

In economics terminology, all goods with an income elasticity of demand greater than zero are "normal", but only the subset having income elasticity of demand > 1 are "superior". [7]

Some articles in the microeconomics discipline use the term superior good as an alternative to an inferior good, thus making "superior goods" and "normal goods" synonymous. Where this is done, a product making up an increasing share of spending under income increases is often called an ultra-superior good.[ citation needed ]

Art history

Secular Rococo luxury or treasure binding for a book, using techniques from the making of gold boxes, in gold, mother of pearl and hardstone, Berlin, 1750-1760. By this time, such lavish bindings were unusual. Ballbuchlein Griot KGM 66-142.jpg
Secular Rococo luxury or treasure binding for a book, using techniques from the making of gold boxes, in gold, mother of pearl and hardstone, Berlin, 1750–1760. By this time, such lavish bindings were unusual.

Though often verging on the meaningless in modern marketing, "luxury" remains a legitimate and current technical term in art history for objects that are especially highly decorated to very high standards and use expensive materials. The term is especially used for medieval manuscripts to distinguish between practical working books for normal use, and fully illuminated manuscripts, that were often bound in treasure bindings with metalwork and jewels. These are often much larger, with less text on each page and many illustrations, and if liturgical texts were originally usually kept on the altar or sacristy rather any library that the church or monastery who owned them may have had. Secular luxury manuscripts were commissioned by the very wealthy and differed in the same ways from cheaper books. [8]

"Luxury" and "luxury arts" may be used for other applied arts where both utilitarian and luxury versions of the same types of objects were made. This might cover metalwork, ceramics, glass, arms and armor, and various objects. [9] It is much less used for objects from the fine arts, with no function beyond being an artwork: paintings, drawings, and sculpture, even though the disparity in cost between an expensive and cheap work may have been as large. [10]

Market

The invention of affordable quartz watches caused mechanical watches to become primarily luxury goods. Patek-Philippe MG 2583.jpg
The invention of affordable quartz watches caused mechanical watches to become primarily luxury goods.
Luxury car Rolls Royce Phantom - Flickr - Alexandre Prevot (5) (cropped).jpg
Luxury car
Seven different types of caviar Seven types of caviar.jpg
Seven different types of caviar
A luxury handbag. While many handbags are valued on their ability to carry objects, designer handbags are valued based on fashion. Kelly Bag.jpg
A luxury handbag. While many handbags are valued on their ability to carry objects, designer handbags are valued based on fashion.

Characteristics

Luxury goods have high income elasticity of demand: as people become wealthier, they will buy proportionately more luxury goods. This also means that should there be a decline in income, its demand will drop more than proportionately. The income elasticity of demand is not constant with respect to income and may change signs at different income levels. That is to say, a luxury good may become a necessity good or even an inferior good at different income levels.

Some luxury products have been claimed to be examples of Veblen goods, with a positive price elasticity of demand: for example, making a perfume more expensive can increase its perceived value as a luxury good to such an extent that sales can go up, rather than down. However, Veblen goods are not synonymous with luxury goods.

Although the technical term luxury good is independent of the goods' quality, they are generally considered to be goods at the highest end of the market in terms of quality and price. Many markets have a luxury segment including, for example, luxury versions of automobiles, yachts, wine, bottled water, coffee, tea, foods, watches, clothes, jewelry, cosmetics and high fidelity sound equipment. [11] Luxuries may be services. Hiring full-time or live-in domestic servants is a luxury reflecting income disparities. Some financial services, especially in some brokerage houses, can be considered luxury services by default because persons in lower-income brackets generally do not use them.

Luxury goods often have special luxury packaging to differentiate the products from mainstream competitors.

Originally, luxury goods were available only to the very wealthy and "aristocratic world of old money" that offered them a history of tradition, superior quality, and a pampered buying experience. [12] Luxury goods have been transformed by a shift from custom-made (bespoke) works with exclusive distribution practices by specialized, quality-minded family-run and small businesses to a mass production of specialty branded goods by profit-focused large corporations and marketers. [12] The trend in modern luxury is simply a product or service that is marketed, packaged, and sold by global corporations that are focused "on growth, visibility, brand awareness, advertising, and, above all, profits." [12] Increasingly, luxury logos are now available to all consumers at a premium price across the world, including online. [13]

Global consumer companies, such as Procter & Gamble, are also attracted to the industry due to the difficulty of making a profit in the mass consumer goods market. [14] The customer base for various luxury goods continue to be more culturally diversified, and this presents more unseen challenges and new opportunities to companies in this industry. [15]

There are several trends in luxury: [16]

Size

The luxury goods market has been on an upward climb for many years. Apart from the setback caused by the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis, the industry has performed well, particularly in 2000. That year, the world luxury goods market was worth nearly $170 billion and grew 7.9 percent. [23] The United States has been the largest regional market for luxury goods. The largest sector in this category was luxury drinks, including premium whisky, champagne, and cognac.[ citation needed ] The watches and jewelry section showed the strongest performance, growing in value by 23.3 percent, while the clothing and accessories section grew 11.6 percent between 1996 and 2000, to $32.8 billion. The largest ten markets for luxury goods account for 83 percent of overall sales and include Brazil, China, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Russia, Spain, Switzerland and United Kingdom, and United States.[ citation needed ]

In 2012, China surpassed Japan as the world's largest luxury market. [24] China's luxury consumption accounts for over 25% of the global market. [25] According to the Global Wealth and Lifestyle Report 2020, Hong Kong, Shanghai, Tokyo and Singapore were four of the five most expensive cities for luxury goods in Asia. [26] In 2014, the luxury sector was expected to grow over the following ten years because of 440 million consumers spending a total of 880 billion euros, or $1.2 trillion. [27]

Advertising

The advertising expenditure for the average luxury brand is 5-15% of sales revenue, or about 25% with the inclusion of other communications such as public relations, events, and sponsorships. [28]

A rather small group in comparison, the wealthy tend to be extremely influential. [29] Once a brand gets an "endorsement" from members of this group, then the brand can be defined as a true "luxury" brand. An example of different product lines in the same brand is found in the automotive industry, with "entry-level" cars marketed to younger, less wealthy consumers, and higher-cost models for older and more wealthy consumers. [30]

Economics

Engels curves showing income elasticity of demand (YED) of normal goods (comprising luxury (red) and necessity goods (yellow)), perfectly inelastic (green) and inferior goods (blue) Income elasticity of demand graph.svg
Engels curves showing income elasticity of demand (YED) of normal goods (comprising luxury (red) and necessity goods (yellow)), perfectly inelastic (green) and inferior goods (blue)

In economics, superior goods or luxury goods make up a larger proportion of consumption as income rises, and therefore are a type of normal goods in consumer theory. Such a good must possess two economic characteristics: it must be scarce, and, along with that, it must have a high price. [31] The scarcity of the good can be natural or artificial; however, the general population (i.e., consumers) must recognize the good as distinguishably better. Possession of such a good usually signifies "superiority" in resources and is usually accompanied by prestige.

A Veblen good is a superior good with a prestige value so high that a price decline might lower demand. Veblen's contribution is demonstrated by the significance of the Veblen effect, which refers to the phenomenon of people purchasing costly items even when more affordable options that provide similar levels of satisfaction are available. [32]

The income elasticity of a superior good is above one by definition because it raises the expenditure share as income rises. A superior good may also be a luxury good that is not purchased below a certain income level. Examples would include smoked salmon, caviar, [31] and most other delicacies. On the other hand, superior goods may have a wide quality distribution, such as wine and holidays. However, though the number of such goods consumed may stay constant even with rising wealth, the level of spending will go up to secure a better experience.

A higher income inequality leads to higher consumption of luxury goods because of status anxiety. [33] [34]

Socioeconomic significance

Crown of Empress Farah Pahlavi of Iran Vystava valtice6.JPG
Crown of Empress Farah Pahlavi of Iran

Several manufactured products attain the status of "luxury goods" due to their design, quality, durability, or performance, which are superior to comparable substitutes. [35]

Some goods are perceived as luxurious by the public simply because they play the role of status symbols, as such goods tend to signify the purchasing power of those who acquire them.[ citation needed ] These items, while not necessarily being better (in quality, performance, or appearance) than their less expensive substitutes, are purchased with the main purpose of displaying wealth or income of their owners.[ citation needed ] These kinds of goods are the objects of a socio-economic phenomenon called conspicuous consumption and commonly include luxury cars, watches, jewelry, designer clothing, yachts, private jets, corporate helicopters as well as large residences, urban mansions, and country houses.[ citation needed ]

Luxury brands

The idea of a luxury brand is not necessarily a product or a price point, but a mindset where core values that are expressed by a brand are directly connected to the producer's dedication and alignment to perceptions of quality with its customers' values and aspirations. [36] Thus, it is these target customers, not the product, that make a luxury brand. [36] Brands considered luxury connect with their customers by communicating that they are at the top of their class or considered the best in their field. [37] Furthermore, these brands must deliver – in some meaningful way – measurably better performance. [37]

What consumers perceive as luxurious brands and products change over the years, but there appear to be three main drivers: (1) a high price, especially when compared to other brands within its segment; (2) limited supply, in that a brand may not need to be expensive, but it arguably should not be easily obtainable and contributing to the customers' feeling that they have something special; and (3) endorsement by celebrities, which can make a brand or particular products more appealing for consumers and thus more "luxurious" in their minds. [38] Two additional elements of luxury brands include special packaging and personalization. [38] These differentiating elements distance the brands from the mass market and thus provide them with a unique feeling and user experience as well as a special and memorable "luxury feel" for customers. [38]

Examples include LVMH, the largest luxury goods producer in the world with over fifty brands (including Louis Vuitton) [39] and sales of €42.6 billion in 2017, [40] Kering, which made €15.9 billion in revenue for a net income of €2.3 billion in 2019, [41] and Richemont.

The luxury brand concept is now so popular that it is used in almost every retail, manufacturing, and service sector. [42] New marketing concepts such as "mass-luxury" or "hyper luxury" further blur the definition of what is a luxury product, a luxury brand, or a luxury company. [42] Lately, luxury brands have extended their reach to young consumers through unconventional luxury brand collaborations in which luxury brands partner with non-luxury brands seemingly at the opposite spectrum of design, image, and value. [20] For example, luxury fashion houses partner with streetwear brands and video games. [43]

Luxury boutiques

The sale of luxury goods requires a high level of client service, human touch, and brand consistency. Since the early 2010s, many luxury brands have invested in their own boutiques rather than wholesalers like department stores. Three of the world’s biggest luxury conglomerates— LVMH, Kering, and Richemont — significantly increased the share of annual sales captured from their directly operated stores and e-commerce over the past decade. [44] [45]

Luxury brands use distinct boutique types to tailor the experiences of different client groups.

Flagship boutiques

Flagship boutiques are grand, multi-story boutiques in major cities that are merchandised with a wide range of collections and staffed by a large team of sales associates. They also offer supplemental services, like jewelry cleaning, hot stamping, on-site service. [46]

Many luxury brands use flagship boutiques to illustrate their unique vision or heritage, [47] often through distinctive architecture [48] that transforms them from storefronts to tourist attractions. [49]

Secondary boutiques

Large cities often have secondary boutiques in addition to their flagship boutique. Multiple boutiques allow luxury brands to cater to different types of clients, which can differ even within small geographic areas. Secondary boutiques often offer different merchandise than flagship boutiques, and establish different types of relationships with clients. [50]

Luxury boutiques in smaller cities are often secondary boutiques as well. [46] The rising popularity of secondary and tertiary cities around the world has pushed luxury brands to open secondary boutiques in smaller cities than those that can support a flagship boutique. [51]

Seasonal boutiques

Luxury brands use seasonal boutiques to follow their well-heeled clientele as they leave major cities for smaller resort towns in the summer and winter. [52] Common throughout Europe, seasonal boutiques have short-term leases, like a pop-up shop, which are open only during the resort's high season. [46] These boutiques offer merchandise relevant to the resort where they are located, like a cruise collection in a beach resort [53] or skiwear in a mountain resort. [54]

Luxury department stores

Most clothing in the world is sold in finished condition in standardized sizes. Luxury stores such as this one produce bespoke clothing--clothing specifically designed for the person buying them. Brioniboutique.jpg
Most clothing in the world is sold in finished condition in standardized sizes. Luxury stores such as this one produce bespoke clothing—clothing specifically designed for the person buying them.

Since the development of mass-market "luxury" brands in the 1800s. Extraordinary places will be the factor of development that can be achieved by enabling the conversion of items from the mass-market to the luxury market.

Many innovative technologies are being added to mass-market products and then transformed into luxury items to be placed in department stores. [55]

Department stores that sell major luxury brands have opened up in most major cities worldwide. Le Bon Marché in Paris, France is credited as one of the first of its kind.

In the United States, the development of luxury-oriented department stores not only changed the retail industry, but also ushered the idea of freedom through consumerism, and a new opportunity for middle- and upper-class women. [56]

Luxury shopping districts

Fashion brands within the luxury goods market tend to be concentrated in exclusive or affluent districts of cities worldwide. These include:

Celebrity influence on luxury goods

Celebrities have played a transformative role in elevating the appeal and desirability of luxury goods, acting as key drivers of consumer trends in the global market. With the advent of social media platforms like Instagram, TikTok, and YouTube, their influence has grown exponentially, creating an immediate impact on consumer behavior. Posts and appearances featuring luxury items often lead to global trends, with high-end brands gaining significant visibility and desirability. [71]

Jewelry and accessories

Luxury jewelry, particularly diamond rings, has benefited immensely from celebrity influence. High-profile figures, including Beyoncé, Jennifer Lopez, and Victoria Beckham, have popularized extravagant diamond rings, especially for engagements and anniversaries. Public appearances showcasing such pieces often inspire consumer interest in similar designs, driving demand for both custom and branded luxury jewelry. [72] [73]

Designer apparel and accessories

Red carpet events, such as the Academy Awards, Cannes Film Festival, and Met Gala, serve as platforms for celebrities to present the latest offerings from high-end fashion houses. For instance, Zendaya’s collaborations with Valentino and Bulgari have reinforced these brands’ status as symbols of opulence. Such visibility enhances brand recognition and boosts sales among consumers eager to emulate celebrity styles. [74] [75]

Luxury perfumes and watches

Luxury perfumes and watches have long leveraged celebrity endorsements to solidify their market presence. For example, George Clooney's association with Omega watches and Charlize Theron’s campaign for Dior’s J'adore perfume exemplify how celebrity partnerships create a strong emotional connection with products. These endorsements often result in increased sales and further embed these items as essentials in the luxury sector. [76] [77]

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Index of economics articles</span>

This aims to be a complete article list of economics topics:

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Consumerism</span> Aspect of socio-economic order

Consumerism is a social and economic order in which the aspirations of many individuals include the acquisition of goods and services beyond those necessary for survival or traditional displays of status. It emerged in Western Europe before the Industrial Revolution and became widespread around 1900. In economics, consumerism refers to policies that emphasize consumption. It is the consideration that the free choice of consumers should strongly inform the choice by manufacturers of what is produced and how, and therefore influence the economic organization of a society.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Elasticity (economics)</span> Economic principle

In economics, elasticity measures the responsiveness of one economic variable to a change in another. For example, if the price elasticity of the demand of a good is −2, then a 10% increase in price will cause the quantity demanded to fall by 20%. Elasticity in economics provides an understanding of changes in the behavior of the buyers and sellers with price changes. There are two types of elasticity for demand and supply, one is inelastic demand and supply and the other one is elastic demand and supply.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Conspicuous consumption</span> Concept in sociology and economy

In sociology and in economics, the term conspicuous consumption describes and explains the consumer practice of buying and using goods of a higher quality, price, or in greater quantity than practical. In 1899, the sociologist Thorstein Veblen coined the term conspicuous consumption to explain the spending of money on and the acquiring of luxury commodities specifically as a public display of economic power—the income and the accumulated wealth—of the buyer. To the conspicuous consumer, the public display of discretionary income is an economic means of either attaining or maintaining a given social status.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Pricing</span> Process of determining what a company will receive in exchange for its products

Pricing is the process whereby a business sets and displays the price at which it will sell its products and services and may be part of the business's marketing plan. In setting prices, the business will take into account the price at which it could acquire the goods, the manufacturing cost, the marketplace, competition, market condition, brand, and quality of the product.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Giffen good</span> Product that people consume more of as the price rises

In microeconomics and consumer theory, a Giffen good is a product that people consume more of as the price rises and vice versa, violating the law of demand.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Inferior good</span> Concept in economics

In economics, inferior goods are those goods the demand for which falls with increase in income of the consumer. So, there is an inverse relationship between income of the consumer and the demand for inferior goods. There are many examples of inferior goods, including cheap cars, public transit options, payday lending, and inexpensive food. The shift in consumer demand for an inferior good can be explained by two natural economic phenomena: the substitution effect and the income effect.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Normal good</span> Good that increases in demand when incomes rise

In economics, a normal good is a type of a good which experiences an increase in demand due to an increase in income, unlike inferior goods, for which the opposite is observed. When there is an increase in a person's income, for example due to a wage rise, a good for which the demand rises due to the wage increase, is referred as a normal good. Conversely, the demand for normal goods declines when the income decreases, for example due to a wage decrease or layoffs.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Veblen good</span> Luxury good for which the demand increases as the price increases

A Veblen good is a type of luxury good, named after American economist Thorstein Veblen, for which the demand increases as the price increases, in apparent contradiction of the law of demand, resulting in an upward-sloping demand curve. The higher prices of Veblen goods may make them desirable as a status symbol in the practices of conspicuous consumption and conspicuous leisure. A product may be a Veblen good because it is a positional good, something few others can own.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Substitute good</span> Economics concept of goods considered interchangeable

In microeconomics, substitute goods are two goods that can be used for the same purpose by consumers. That is, a consumer perceives both goods as similar or comparable, so that having more of one good causes the consumer to desire less of the other good. Contrary to complementary goods and independent goods, substitute goods may replace each other in use due to changing economic conditions. An example of substitute goods is Coca-Cola and Pepsi; the interchangeable aspect of these goods is due to the similarity of the purpose they serve, i.e. fulfilling customers' desire for a soft drink. These types of substitutes can be referred to as close substitutes.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Law of demand</span> Fundamental principle in microeconomics

In microeconomics, the law of demand is a fundamental principle which states that there is an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded. In other words, "conditional on all else being equal, as the price of a good increases (↑), quantity demanded will decrease (↓); conversely, as the price of a good decreases (↓), quantity demanded will increase (↑)". Alfred Marshall worded this as: "When we say that a person's demand for anything increases, we mean that he will buy more of it than he would before at the same price, and that he will buy as much of it as before at a higher price". The law of demand, however, only makes a qualitative statement in the sense that it describes the direction of change in the amount of quantity demanded but not the magnitude of change.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Consumer behaviour</span> Study of individuals, groups, or organisations and all the activities associated with consuming

Consumer behaviour is the study of individuals, groups, or organisations and all activities associated with the purchase, use and disposal of goods and services. It encompasses how the consumer's emotions, attitudes, and preferences affect buying behaviour. Consumer behaviour emerged in the 1940–1950s as a distinct sub-discipline of marketing, but has become an interdisciplinary social science that blends elements from psychology, sociology, social anthropology, anthropology, ethnography, ethnology, marketing, and economics.

The snob effect is a phenomenon described in microeconomics as a situation where the demand for a certain good by individuals of a higher income level is inversely related to its demand by those of a lower income level. The "snob effect" contrasts most other microeconomic models, in that the demand curve can have a positive slope, rather than the typical negatively sloped demand curve of normal goods.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Demand</span> Concept in economics

In economics, demand is the quantity of a good that consumers are willing and able to purchase at various prices during a given time. In economics "demand" for a commodity is not the same thing as "desire" for it. It refers to both the desire to purchase and the ability to pay for a commodity.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Fast fashion</span> Quick retail copying of catwalk trends

Fast fashion is the business model of replicating recent catwalk trends and high-fashion designs, mass-producing them at a low cost, and bringing them to retail quickly while demand is at its highest. The term fast fashion is also used generically to describe the products of this business model, particularly clothing and footwear. Retailers who employ the fast fashion strategy include Primark, H&M, Shein, and Zara, all of which have become large multinationals by driving high turnover of inexpensive seasonal and trendy clothing that appeals to fashion-conscious consumers.

The consumer revolution refers to the period from approximately 1600 to 1750 in England in which there was a marked increase in the consumption and variety of luxury goods and products by individuals from different economic and social backgrounds. The consumer revolution marked a departure from the traditional mode of life that was dominated by frugality and scarcity to one of increasingly mass consumption in society.

In economics, the income elasticity of demand (YED) is the responsivenesses of the quantity demanded for a good to a change in consumer income. It is measured as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in income. For example, if in response to a 10% increase in income, quantity demanded for a good or service were to increase by 20%, the income elasticity of demand would be 20%/10% = 2.0.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Luxury packaging</span> Type of packaging

Luxury and specialty packaging is the design, research, development, and manufacturing of packaging, displays, and for luxury brands. The packaging of a luxury product is part of the brand’s image and research shows consumers are willing to spend more on products if the packaging looks appealing and luxurious.

Massification is a strategy that some luxury companies use to expose their brands to a broader market and increase sales. As a method of implementing massification, companies have created diffusion lines. Diffusion lines are an offshoot of a company or a designer's original line that is less expensive in order to reach a broader market and gain a wider consumer base. Another strategy used in massification is brand extensions, which is when an already established company releases a new product under their name.

Hype in marketing is a strategy of using extreme publicity. Hype as a modern marketing strategy is closely associated with social media.

References

  1. Varian, Hal (1992). "Choice". Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: W.W. Norton. p.  117. ISBN   978-0-393-95735-8 . Retrieved 4 October 2019. [...] as the consumer gets more income, he consumes more of both goods but proportionally more of one good (the luxury good) than of the other (the necessary good).
  2. Lapatin, 1-2
  3. 1 2 Roberts, David (20 March 2020). "Why rich people use so much more energy". vox.com. Retrieved 22 March 2020.
  4. Wong, N.Y.; Ahuvia, A. C. (1998). "Personal taste and family face: Luxury consumption in Confucian and Western societies". Psychology & Marketing. 15 (5): 423–441. doi:10.1002/(SICI)1520-6793(199808)15:5<423::AID-MAR2>3.0.CO;2-9. S2CID   55715301.
  5. "What is luxury?". pauravshukla.com. 14 May 2010. Retrieved 9 August 2010.
  6. Holmqvist, Jonas; Diaz Ruiz, Carlos; Peñaloza, Lisa (1 August 2020). "Moments of luxury: Hedonic escapism as a luxury experience". Journal of Business Research. 116: 503–513. doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.10.015 . S2CID   211427257.
  7. "superior good". businessdictionary.com. 2011. Archived from the original on 8 February 2011. Retrieved 3 January 2023.
  8. Kren, Thomas (2009). Illuminated manuscripts of Germany and Central Europe in the J. Paul Getty Museum. Los Angeles: J. Paul Getty museum. pp. 7–9. ISBN   9780892369485.
  9. Belozerskaya, Marina (2005). Luxury arts of the Renaissance. Los Angeles: J. Paul Getty Museum. pp. Lapatin, 1–10. ISBN   9780892367856.
  10. Lapatin, 9
  11. Kenton, Will. "What Is Luxury Item?". investopedia.com. Retrieved 30 September 2019.
  12. 1 2 3 Thomas, Dana (2007). Deluxe: How Luxury Lost Its Luster . Penguin. ISBN   9781594201295.
  13. Danziger, Pamela N. (26 February 2018). "5 Brands That Reveal The Future Of Luxury Online". Forbes. Retrieved 9 October 2019.
  14. "Procter & Gamble Cleans Up With Luxury Paper Towels". bloomberg.com. Retrieved 28 July 2018.
  15. Seo, Yuri; Oliver, Margo Buchanan (2015). "Luxury branding: the industry, trends, and future conceptualisations". Asia Pacific Journal of Marketing and Logistics. 27 (1): 82–98. doi:10.1108/APJML-10-2014-0148.
  16. "Global Luxury Fashion Industry Analysis 2019, Market Growth, Trends, Opportunities Forecast To 2024". erienewsnow.com. Archived from the original on 1 October 2019. Retrieved 1 October 2019.
  17. Silverstein, Michael J.; Fiske, Neil (April 2003). "Luxury for the Masses". Harvard Business Review. ISSN   0017-8012 . Retrieved 12 November 2023.
  18. "The Luxury Industry: Accelerating and Advancing Corporate Responsibility to Meet Evolving Consumer Demands". Boston Consulting Group (BCG) (Press release). 30 June 2022. Retrieved 3 January 2023 via prnewswire.com.
  19. Michel, Chevalier; Lu, Pierre, eds. (2010). "Chinese Consumer Attitudes Toward Luxury". Luxury China: Market Opportunities and Potential. John Wiley & Sons. pp. 53–76. doi:10.1002/9781119199755.ch5. ISBN   9780470823415 . Retrieved 12 November 2023.
  20. 1 2 3 Diaz Ruiz, Carlos; Cruz, Angela Gracia B. (1 January 2023). "Unconventional luxury brand collaborations: a new form of luxury consumption among young adults in China". International Marketing Review. 40 (7): 1–21. doi: 10.1108/IMR-04-2022-0099 . ISSN   0265-1335.
  21. "LVMH, Kering, Richemont? Where to Place Your Bets". The Business of Fashion. 13 June 2016. Retrieved 28 July 2018.
  22. Cruz, Angela; Ruiz, Carlos Diaz (7 August 2023). "Unconventional luxury brand collaborations are everywhere. What is the appeal?". The Conversation. Retrieved 10 August 2023.
  23. "The World Market for Luxury Goods." Global Market for Luxury Goods. Nov 1, 2001, March 5, 2007.
  24. "China bans television ads for bling". 8 February 2013. Retrieved 15 February 2013.
  25. "Export to China". export-to-china.com. Archived from the original on 2 April 2015. Retrieved 18 March 2015.
  26. Gonçalves, Pedro (16 January 2020). "Asia is most expensive region for wealthy". International Investment. Retrieved 9 October 2020.
  27. Zargani, Luisa (28 January 2014). "Luxe Spending to Grow to $1.2 Trillion". wwd.com. Retrieved 29 January 2014.
  28. Okonkwo, Uche (2016). Luxury Fashion Branding: Trends, Tactics, Techniques. Springer. p. 145. ISBN   9780230590885 . Retrieved 4 October 2019.
  29. "Luxury definition in transition: ideal values instead of overconsumption". hausvoneden.com (in German). 14 September 2020. Retrieved 6 July 2021.
  30. "Sustainable Luxuries? Millennials are Skeptical – Yet They Buy". hec.edu. 7 September 2020. Retrieved 6 July 2021.
  31. 1 2 Shellfish Economics A course outline for the FAO of the United Nations; Fisheries and Aquaculture Department. Retrieved 18 April 2008.
  32. Rod, Aleš; Rais, Jonáš; Schwarz, Jiří; Čermáková, Klára (2015). "Economics of Luxury: Counting Probability of Buying Counterfeits of Luxury Goods". Procedia Economics and Finance. 30: 720–729. doi: 10.1016/S2212-5671(15)01321-0 .
  33. "How inequality may be fuelling our obsession with luxury goods". Warwick Business School.
  34. Pybus, Katie; Power, Madeleine; Pickett, Kate E.; Wilkinson, Richard (2022). "Income inequality, status consumption and status anxiety: An exploratory review of implications for sustainability and directions for future research". Social Sciences & Humanities Open. 6 (1): 100353. doi: 10.1016/j.ssaho.2022.100353 .
  35. Parker, Christopher J.; Doyle, Stephen (2018). "1". In Ozuem, Wilson; Azemi, Yllka (eds.). Designing Indulgent Interaction: Luxury Fashion, M-Commerce, and Übermensch. IGI Global. pp. 1–21. ISBN   9781522526971.
  36. 1 2 Danziger, Pamela N. (7 May 2017). "What Makes A Brand Luxury And Why Shinola Earns The Title". Forbes. Retrieved 1 February 2020.
  37. 1 2 Danziger, Pamela N. (13 October 2016). "10 core values that make a brand luxury". BrandKnew Magazine. Retrieved 1 February 2020.
  38. 1 2 3 Eckloff, Lucy (21 May 2018). "Why is a brand considered luxury and why does this change over time?". kadence.com. Retrieved 1 February 2020.
  39. Christensen, Jens (2009). Global Experience Industries: the Business of Experience Economy. Aarhus University Press. ISBN   9788779344327.
  40. "Annual Report 2017 (PDF)" (PDF). LVMH. Retrieved 4 October 2019.
  41. Kering: 2019 Full-year Results, Businesswire.com, 12 February 2020
  42. 1 2 Kapferer, Jean-Noël; Bastien, Vincent (2012). The luxury strategy: break the rules of marketing to build luxury brands (Second ed.). Kogan Page. ISBN   9780749464912.
  43. "Louis Vuitton x League of Legends: what if you dressed as your favorite video game character?". Vogue France (in French). 31 October 2019. Retrieved 29 May 2023.
  44. Bain, Marc (October 10, 2018). "Luxury labels are going direct-to-consumer". Quartz. Retrieved 10 September 2024.
  45. PYMNTS (2024-02-12). "Trouble Ahead for Department Stores as Luxury Brands Move Direct-to-Consumer". PYMNTS.com. Retrieved 2024-09-12.
  46. 1 2 3 Hanyak, Angela (1 October 2023). "Luxury Shopping in Europe: How to Prepare and What to Expect". Notes From Here. Retrieved 14 September 2024.
  47. Quillin, Jessica. "The Strategy of a Luxury Flagship Store". www.fashionstrategyweekly.com. Retrieved 2024-09-14.
  48. Peppin, Hayley (2021-10-28). "Six most architecturally captivating luxury storefronts from around the globe". Harper's Bazaar Australia. Retrieved 2024-09-14.
  49. Zhang, Miles Socha,Tianwei (2023-08-29). "What to Watch: Behold the Super Mega Flagship Store". WWD. Retrieved 2024-09-14.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  50. Nguyen, Janet (2024-06-08). "Why you might find two Louis Vuitton stores on the same block". Marketplace. Retrieved 2024-09-14.
  51. "Smaller cities are unlocking luxury's local future. Here's what you need to know". frameweb.com. Retrieved 2024-09-14.
  52. Fearon, Francesca (2024-07-08). "Luxury brands catch a break from holiday resort boutiques". Financial Times. Retrieved 2024-09-14.
  53. WW, FashionNetwork com. "Louis Vuitton, Gucci, Jacquemus... Luxury takes up residence in Saint-Tropez". FashionNetwork.com. Retrieved 2024-09-14.
  54. "CHANEL's Seasonal Boutiques in Courchevel & Gstaad". L'Officiel Baltic. Retrieved 2024-09-14.
  55. Heine, Klaus; Phan, Michel (May 2011). "Trading-Up Mass-Market Goods to Luxury Products". Australasian Marketing Journal. 19 (2): 108–114. doi:10.1016/j.ausmj.2011.03.001. ISSN   1839-3349. S2CID   167596249.
  56. Blakemore, Erin (19 November 2018). "How 19th-Century Women Used Department Stores to Gain Their Freedom". History. Retrieved 17 January 2020.
  57. "Hermès to open flagship store in Amsterdam". Fashion Network. 2 November 2017. Retrieved 8 September 2024.
  58. "Barcelona's luxury and art street: 200 years of Passeig de Gràcia". Catalan News. 22 July 2023. Retrieved 8 September 2024.
  59. "Newbury Street Shopping". boston-discovery-guide.com. Retrieved 3 March 2024.
  60. Kostaras, Susie (29 January 2013). "Eighteen Stores to Spend It All When You Have Money to Burn". Racked. Retrieved 3 March 2024.
  61. "10 Best Places For Luxury Shopping in Chicago". Discover Walks. 16 July 2023. Retrieved 3 March 2024.
  62. "Shopping in Frankfurt: Hier kann man am besten Mode einkaufen!". Fashion Insider Modeblog. 28 February 2020. Retrieved 8 September 2024.
  63. "After 120 Years, This Munich Jeweler Has Decided to Move". The New York Times. 4 March 2024. Retrieved 8 September 2024.
  64. Eyeman, Scott (31 March 2012). "See Worth Avenue in a whole new way". The Palm Beach Post. Archived from the original on 3 August 2020. Retrieved 3 March 2024.
  65. Webb, Kristina (20 November 2023). "Shop Local: Palm Beach's Worth Ave. offers an iconic restaurant and holiday shopping experience". Palm Beach Daily News. Retrieved 3 March 2024.
  66. "Czech This Out: Luxury Is Flourishing in Prague". Women's Wear Daily. 18 December 2019. Retrieved 8 September 2024.
  67. "High Street's glamour". Eurobuild Central & Eastern Europe. 23 April 2024. Retrieved 8 September 2024.
  68. Sobczyk, Marcin (4 June 2013). "Luxury Retailers Shop Warsaw". The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved 3 March 2024.
  69. Brownell, Ginanne (23 November 2022). "In Warsaw, Mining a Rich Vein of Polish Creativity". The New York Times. Retrieved 3 March 2024.
  70. "The world's most expensive streets". WorldTempus. 11 January 2016. Retrieved 8 September 2024.
  71. Kapferer, Jean-Noël; Bastien, Vincent (2012-09-03). The Luxury Strategy: Break the Rules of Marketing to Build Luxury Brands. Kogan Page Publishers. ISBN   978-0-7494-6492-9.
  72. Foroudi, Pantea; Tortora, Debora. "Celebrity Endorsement and the Attitude Towards Luxury Brands for Sustainable Consumption". ResearchGate . Retrieved 2024-12-16.
  73. Yazdinian, Nouriel Gino. "Wedding Anniversary Diamond Rings: History To Celebrity Influence". NY Elizabeth. Retrieved 2024-12-16.
  74. Chen, Zijun; Zong, Wenwen (2024-03-21). "Influence of Celebrities on the Image Building of Luxury Brands". Highlights in Business, Economics and Management. 27: 165–171. doi:10.54097/mtzg1385. ISSN   2957-952X.
  75. Newbert, Jaclyn. "Celebrity Impact on Fashion Brand Choice Using Social Media". Scholar Commons. Retrieved 2024-12-16.
  76. Collection, Celebs Watch (2023-08-31). "Style and Substance: Exploring the Relationship Between Celebrities and Watch Brands". Medium . Retrieved 2024-12-14.
  77. Markets, Research and (2022-12-14). "Insights on the Luxury Perfume Global Market to 2027 - Rising Influence of Celebrity Endorsements Coupled With the Wide Product Availability on E-Commerce Platforms Drives Growth". GlobeNewswire . Retrieved 2024-12-16.

Further reading