Maximum sustainable yield

Last updated

In population ecology and economics, maximum sustainable yield (MSY) is theoretically, the largest yield (or catch) that can be taken from a species' stock over an indefinite period. Fundamental to the notion of sustainable harvest, the concept of MSY aims to maintain the population size at the point of maximum growth rate by harvesting the individuals that would normally be added to the population, allowing the population to continue to be productive indefinitely. Under the assumption of logistic growth, resource limitation does not constrain individuals' reproductive rates when populations are small, but because there are few individuals, the overall yield is small. At intermediate population densities, also represented by half the carrying capacity, individuals are able to breed to their maximum rate. At this point, called the maximum sustainable yield, there is a surplus of individuals that can be harvested because growth of the population is at its maximum point due to the large number of reproducing individuals. Above this point, density dependent factors increasingly limit breeding until the population reaches carrying capacity. At this point, there are no surplus individuals to be harvested and yield drops to zero. The maximum sustainable yield is usually higher than the optimum sustainable yield and maximum economic yield.

Contents

MSY is extensively used for fisheries management. Unlike the logistic (Schaefer) model, [1] MSY has been refined in most modern fisheries models and occurs at around 30% of the unexploited population size. [2] [3] This fraction differs among populations depending on the life history of the species and the age-specific selectivity of the fishing method.

History

The concept of MSY as a fisheries management strategy developed in Belmar, New Jersey, in the early 1930s. [4] [5] [6] It increased in popularity in the 1950s with the advent of surplus-production models with explicitly estimate MSY. [1] As an apparently simple and logical management goal, combined with the lack of other simple management goals of the time, MSY was adopted as the primary management goal by several international organizations (e.g., IWC, IATTC, [7] ICCAT, ICNAF), and individual countries. [8]

Between 1949 and 1955, the U.S. maneuvered to have MSY declared the goal of international fisheries management (Johnson 2007). The international MSY treaty that was eventually adopted in 1955 gave foreign fleets the right to fish off any coast. Nations that wanted to exclude foreign boats had to first prove that its fish were overfished. [9]

As experience was gained with the model, it became apparent to some researchers that it lacked the capability to deal with the real world operational complexities and the influence of trophic and other interactions. In 1977, Peter Larkin wrote its epitaph, challenging the goal of maximum sustained yield on several grounds: It put populations at too much risk; it did not account for spatial variability in productivity; it did not account for species other than the focus of the fishery; it considered only the benefits, not the costs, of fishing; and it was sensitive to political pressure. [10] In fact, none of these criticisms was aimed at sustainability as a goal. The first one noted that seeking the absolute MSY with uncertain parameters was risky. The rest point out that the goal of MSY was not holistic; it left out too many relevant features. [9]

Some managers began to use more conservative quota recommendations, but the influence of the MSY model for fisheries management still prevailed. Even while the scientific community was beginning to question the appropriateness and effectiveness of MSY as a management goal, [10] [11] it was incorporated into the 1982 United Nations Convention for the Law of the Sea, thus ensuring its integration into national and international fisheries acts and laws. [8] According to Walters and Maguire, an ‘‘institutional juggernaut had been set in motion’’, climaxing in the early 1990s with the collapse of northern cod. [12]

Modelling MSY

Population growth

The key assumption behind all sustainable harvesting models such as MSY is that populations of organisms grow and replace themselves – that is, they are renewable resources. Additionally it is assumed that because the growth rates, survival rates, and reproductive rates increase when harvesting reduces population density, [4] they produce a surplus of biomass that can be harvested. Otherwise, sustainable harvest would not be possible.

Another assumption of renewable resource harvesting is that populations of organisms do not continue to grow indefinitely; they reach an equilibrium population size, which occurs when the number of individuals matches the resources available to the population (i.e., assume classic logistic growth). At this equilibrium population size, called the carrying capacity, the population remains at a stable size. [13]

Figure 1 Logisticpopulationgrowth2.jpg
Figure 1

The logistic model (or logistic function) is a function that is used to describe bounded population growth under the previous two assumptions. The logistic function is bounded at both extremes: when there are not individuals to reproduce, and when there is an equilibrium number of individuals (i.e., at carrying capacity). Under the logistic model, population growth rate between these two limits is most often assumed to be sigmoidal (Figure 1). There is scientific evidence that some populations do grow in a logistic fashion towards a stable equilibrium – a commonly cited example is the logistic growth of yeast.

The equation describing logistic growth is: [13]

(equation 1.1)

The parameter values are:

=The population size at time t
=The carrying capacity of the population
= The population size at time zero
= the intrinsic rate of population increase (the rate at which the population grows when it is very small)

From the logistic function, the population size at any point can be calculated as long as , , and are known.

Figure 2 Growthratevs.populationsize.jpg
Figure 2

Differentiating equation 1.1 give an expression for how the rate of population increases as N increases. At first, the population growth rate is fast, but it begins to slow as the population grows until it levels off to the maximum growth rate, after which it begins to decrease (figure 2).

The equation for figure 2 is the differential of equation 1.1 (Verhulst's 1838 growth model): [13]

(equation 1.2)

can be understood as the change in population (N) with respect to a change in time (t). Equation 1.2 is the usual way in which logistic growth is represented mathematically and has several important features. First, at very low population sizes, the value of is small, so the population growth rate is approximately equal to , meaning the population is growing exponentially at a rate r (the intrinsic rate of population increase). Despite this, the population growth rate is very low (low values on the y-axis of figure 2) because, even though each individual is reproducing at a high rate, there are few reproducing individuals present. Conversely, when the population is large the value of approaches 1 effectively reducing the terms inside the brackets of equation 1.2 to zero. The effect is that the population growth rate is again very low, because either each individual is hardly reproducing or mortality rates are high. [13] As a result of these two extremes, the population growth rate is maximum at an intermediate population or half the carrying capacity ().

MSY model

Figure 3 Harvestingrates.jpg
Figure 3

The simplest way to model harvesting is to modify the logistic equation so that a certain number of individuals is continuously removed: [13]

(equation 1.3)

Where H represents the number of individuals being removed from the population – that is, the harvesting rate. When H is constant, the population will be at equilibrium when the number of individuals being removed is equal to the population growth rate (figure 3). The equilibrium population size under a particular harvesting regime can be found when the population is not growing – that is, when . This occurs when the population growth rate is the same as the harvest rate:

Figure 3 shows how growth rate varies with population density. For low densities (far from carrying capacity), there is little addition (or "recruitment") to the population, simply because there are few organisms to give birth. At high densities, though, there is intense competition for resources, and growth rate is again low because the death rate is high. In between these two extremes, the population growth rate rises to a maximum value (). This maximum point represents the maximum number of individuals that can be added to a population by natural processes. If more individuals than this are removed from the population, the population is at risk for decline to extinction. [14] The maximum number that can be harvested in a sustainable manner, called the maximum sustainable yield, is given by this maximum point.

Figure 3 also shows several possible values for the harvesting rate, H. At , there are two possible population equilibrium points: a low population size () and a high one (). At , a slightly higher harvest rate, however there is only one equilibrium point (at ), which is the population size that produces the maximum growth rate. With logistic growth, this point, called the maximum sustainable yield, is where the population size is half the carrying capacity (or ). The maximum sustainable yield is the largest yield that can be taken from a population at equilibrium. In figure 3, if is higher than , the harvesting would exceed the population's capacity to replace itself at any population size ( in figure 3). Because harvesting rate is higher than the population growth rate at all values of , this rate of harvesting is not sustainable.

An important feature of the MSY model is how harvested populations respond to environmental fluctuations or illegal offtake. Consider a population at harvested at a constant harvest level . If the population falls (due to a bad winter or illegal harvest) this will ease density-dependent population regulation and increase yield, moving the population back to , a stable equilibrium. In this case, a negative feedback loop creates stability. The lower equilibrium point for the constant harvest level is not stable however; a population crash or illegal harvesting will decrease population yield farther below the current harvest level, creating a positive feedback loop leading to extinction. Harvesting at is also potentially unstable. A small decrease in the population can lead to a positive feedback loop and extinction if the harvesting regime () is not reduced. Thus, some consider harvesting at MSY to be unsafe on ecological and economic grounds. [14] [15] The MSY model itself can be modified to harvest a certain percentage of the population or with constant effort constraints rather than an actual number, thereby avoiding some of its instabilities. [14]

The MSY equilibrium point is semi-stable – a small increase in population size is compensated for, a small decrease to extinction if H is not decreased. Harvesting at MSY is therefore dangerous because it is on a knife-edge – any small population decline leads to a positive feedback, with the population declining rapidly to extinction if the number of harvested stays the same. [14] [15]

The formula for maximum sustained harvest () is one-fourth the maximum population or carrying capacity () times the intrinsic rate of growth (). [16]

For demographically structured populations

The principle of MSY often holds for age-structured populations as well. [17] The calculations can be more complicated, and the results often depend on whether density dependence occurs in the larval stage (often modeled as density dependent reproduction) and/or other life stages. [18] It has been shown that if density dependence only acts on larva, then there is an optimal life stage (size or age class) to harvest, with no harvest of all other life stages. [17] Hence the optimal strategy is to harvest this most valuable life-stage at MSY. [19] However, in age and stage-structured models, a constant MSY does not always exist. In such cases, cyclic harvest is optimal where the yield and resource fluctuate in size, through time. [20] In addition, environmental stochasticity interacts with demographically structured populations in fundamentally different ways than for unstructured populations when determining optimal harvest. In fact, the optimal biomass to be left in the ocean, when fished at MSY, can be either higher or lower than in analogous deterministic models, depending on the details of the density dependent recruitment function, if stage-structure is also included in the model. [21]

Implications of MSY model

Starting to harvest a previously unharvested population will always lead to a decrease in the population size. That is, it is impossible for a harvested population to remain at its original carrying capacity. Instead, the population will either stabilize at a new lower equilibrium size or, if the harvesting rate is too high, decline to zero.

The reason why populations can be sustainably harvested is that they exhibit a density-dependent response. [14] [15] This means that at any population size below K, the population is producing a surplus yield that is available for harvesting without reducing population size. Density dependence is the regulator process that allows the population to return to equilibrium after a perturbation. The logistic equation assumes that density dependence takes the form of negative feedback. [15]

If a constant number of individuals is harvested from a population at a level greater than the MSY, the population will decline to extinction. Harvesting below the MSY level leads to a stable equilibrium population if the starting population is above the unstable equilibrium population size.

Uses of MSY

MSY has been especially influential in the management of renewable biological resources such as commercially important fish and wildlife. In fisheries terms, maximum sustainable yield (MSY) is the largest average catch that can be captured from a stock under existing environmental conditions. [22] MSY aims at a balance between too much and too little harvest to keep the population at some intermediate abundance with a maximum replacement rate.

Relating to MSY, the maximum economic yield (MEY) is the level of catch that provides the maximum net economic benefits or profits to society. [23] [24] Like optimum sustainable yield, MEY is usually less than MSY.

Limitations of MSY approach

Although it is widely practiced by state and federal government agencies regulating wildlife, forests, and fishing, MSY has come under heavy criticism by ecologists and others from both theoretical and practical reasons. [15] The concept of maximum sustainable yield is not always easy to apply in practice. Estimation problems arise due to poor assumptions in some models and lack of reliability of the data. [8] [25] Biologists, for example, do not always have enough data to make a clear determination of the population's size and growth rate. Calculating the point at which a population begins to slow from competition is also very difficult. The concept of MSY also tends to treat all individuals in the population as identical, thereby ignoring all aspects of population structure such as size or age classes and their differential rates of growth, survival, and reproduction. [25]

As a management goal, the static interpretation of MSY (i.e., MSY as a fixed catch that can be taken year after year) is generally not appropriate because it ignores the fact that fish populations undergo natural fluctuations (i.e., MSY treats the environment as unvarying) in abundance and will usually ultimately become severely depleted under a constant-catch strategy. [25] Thus, most fisheries scientists now interpret MSY in a more dynamic sense as the maximum average yield (MAY) obtained by applying a specific harvesting strategy to a fluctuating resource. [8] Or as an optimal "escapement strategy", where escapement means the amount of fish that must remain in the ocean [rather than the amount of fish that can be harvested]. An escapement strategy is often the optimal strategy for maximizing expected yield of a harvested, stochastically fluctuating population. [26]

However, the limitations of MSY, does not mean it performs worse than humans using their best intuitive judgment. Experiments using students in natural resource management classes suggest that people using their past experience, intuition, and best judgement to manage a fishery generate far less long term yield compared to a computer using an MSY calculation, even when that calculation comes from incorrect population dynamic models. [27]

For a more contemporary description of MSY and its calculation see [28]

Orange roughy

An example of errors in estimating the population dynamics of a species occurred within the New Zealand Orange roughy fishery. Early quotas were based on an assumption that the orange roughy had a fairly short lifespan and bred relatively quickly. However, it was later discovered that the orange roughy lived a long time and had bred slowly (~30 years). By this stage stocks had been largely depleted.[ citation needed ]

Criticism

The approach has been widely criticized as ignoring several key factors involved in fisheries management and has led to the devastating collapse of many fisheries. Among conservation biologists it is widely regarded as dangerous and misused. [29] [12]

Overfishing

Across the world there is a crisis in the world's fisheries. [30] In recent years an accelerating decline has been observed in the productivity of many important fisheries. [31] Fisheries which have been devastated in recent times include (but are not limited to) the great whale fisheries, the Grand Bank fisheries of the western Atlantic, and the Peruvian anchovy fishery. [32] Recent assessments by the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the state of the world's fisheries indicate a levelling off of landings in the 1990s, at about 100 million tons. [33]

In addition, the composition of global catches has changed. [34] As fishers deplete larger, long-lived predatory fish species such as cod, tuna, shark, and snapper, they move down to the next level – to species that tend to be smaller, shorter-lived, and less valuable. [35]

Overfishing is a classic example of the tragedy of the commons. [32]

Optimum sustainable yield

In population ecology and economics, optimum sustainable yield is the level of effort (LOE) that maximizes the difference between total revenue and total cost. Or, where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. This level of effort maximizes the economic profit, or rent, of the resource being utilized. It usually corresponds to an effort level lower than that of maximum sustainable yield. In environmental science, optimum sustainable yield is the largest economical yield of a renewable resource achievable over a long time period without decreasing the ability of the population or its environment to support the continuation of this level of yield.

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Theoretical ecology</span>

Theoretical ecology is the scientific discipline devoted to the study of ecological systems using theoretical methods such as simple conceptual models, mathematical models, computational simulations, and advanced data analysis. Effective models improve understanding of the natural world by revealing how the dynamics of species populations are often based on fundamental biological conditions and processes. Further, the field aims to unify a diverse range of empirical observations by assuming that common, mechanistic processes generate observable phenomena across species and ecological environments. Based on biologically realistic assumptions, theoretical ecologists are able to uncover novel, non-intuitive insights about natural processes. Theoretical results are often verified by empirical and observational studies, revealing the power of theoretical methods in both predicting and understanding the noisy, diverse biological world.

The carrying capacity of an environment is the maximum population size of a biological species that can be sustained by that specific environment, given the food, habitat, water, and other resources available. The carrying capacity is defined as the environment's maximal load, which in population ecology corresponds to the population equilibrium, when the number of deaths in a population equals the number of births. The effect of carrying capacity on population dynamics is modelled with a logistic function. Carrying capacity is applied to the maximum population an environment can support in ecology, agriculture and fisheries. The term carrying capacity has been applied to a few different processes in the past before finally being applied to population limits in the 1950s. The notion of carrying capacity for humans is covered by the notion of sustainable population.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Logistic function</span> S-shaped curve

A logistic function or logistic curve is a common S-shaped curve with the equation

The Lotka–Volterra equations, also known as the Lotka–Volterra predator–prey model, are a pair of first-order nonlinear differential equations, frequently used to describe the dynamics of biological systems in which two species interact, one as a predator and the other as prey. The populations change through time according to the pair of equations:

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Pierre François Verhulst</span> Belgian mathematician

Pierre François Verhulst was a Belgian mathematician and a doctor in number theory from the University of Ghent in 1825. He is best known for the logistic growth model.

Population dynamics is the type of mathematics used to model and study the size and age composition of populations as dynamical systems.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Population ecology</span> Study of the dynamics of species populations and how these populations interact with the environment

Population ecology is a sub-field of ecology that deals with the dynamics of species populations and how these populations interact with the environment, such as birth and death rates, and by immigration and emigration.

The Allee effect is a phenomenon in biology characterized by a correlation between population size or density and the mean individual fitness of a population or species.

The Gompertz curve or Gompertz function is a type of mathematical model for a time series, named after Benjamin Gompertz (1779–1865). This function derives the formula for yx+b^x with logarithm. Dr. Allen is a key import in this equation. It is a sigmoid function which describes growth as being slowest at the start and end of a given time period. The right-side or future value asymptote of the function is approached much more gradually by the curve than the left-side or lower valued asymptote. This is in contrast to the simple logistic function in which both asymptotes are approached by the curve symmetrically. It is a special case of the generalised logistic function. The function was originally designed to describe human mortality, but since has been modified to be applied in biology, with regard to detailing populations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Milner Baily Schaefer</span>

Milner Baily ("Benny") Schaefer, is notable for his work on the population dynamics of fisheries.

In forestry, the optimal rotation age is the growth period required to derive maximum value from a stand of timber. The calculation of this period is specific to each stand and to the economic and sustainability goals of the harvester.

The Beverton–Holt model is a classic discrete-time population model which gives the expected number n t+1 of individuals in generation t + 1 as a function of the number of individuals in the previous generation,

A population model is a type of mathematical model that is applied to the study of population dynamics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Biological exponential growth</span>

Biological exponential growth is the unrestricted growth of a population of organisms, occurring when resources in its habitat are unlimited. Most commonly apparent in species that reproduce quickly and asexually, like bacteria, exponential growth is intuitive from the fact that each organism can divide and produce two copies of itself. Each descendent bacterium can itself divide, again doubling the population size. The bacterium Escherichia coli, under optimal conditions, may divide as often as twice per hour. Left unrestricted, a colony would cover the Earth's surface in less than a day.

The sustainable yield of natural capital is the ecological yield that can be extracted without reducing the base of capital itself, i.e. the surplus required to maintain ecosystem services at the same or increasing level over time. This yield usually varies over time with the needs of the ecosystem to maintain itself, e.g. a forest that has recently suffered a blight or flooding or fire will require more of its own ecological yield to sustain and re-establish a mature forest. While doing so, the sustainable yield may be much less.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Population dynamics of fisheries</span>

A fishery is an area with an associated fish or aquatic population which is harvested for its commercial or recreational value. Fisheries can be wild or farmed. Population dynamics describes the ways in which a given population grows and shrinks over time, as controlled by birth, death, and migration. It is the basis for understanding changing fishery patterns and issues such as habitat destruction, predation and optimal harvesting rates. The population dynamics of fisheries is used by fisheries scientists to determine sustainable yields.

Fish mortality is a parameter used in fisheries population dynamics to account for the loss of fish in a fish stock through death. The mortality can be divided into two types:

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Stock assessment</span> Process used in fisheries management

Stock assessments provide fisheries managers with the information that is used in the regulation of a fish stock. Biological and fisheries data are collected in a stock assessment.

The paradox of the pesticides is a paradox that states that applying pesticide to a pest may end up increasing the abundance of the pest if the pesticide upsets natural predator–prey dynamics in the ecosystem.

The Gordon-Schaefer model is a bioeconomic model applied in the fishing industry. It may be used to compute the maximum sustainable yield. It takes account of biological growth rates, carrying capacity, and total and marginal costs and revenues.

References

  1. 1 2 Schaefer, Milner B. (1954), "Some aspects of the dynamics of populations important to the management of commercial marine fisheries", Bulletin of the Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission (reprinted in Bulletin of Mathematical Biology, Vol. 53, No. 1/2, pp. 253-279, 1991 ed.), 1 (2): 27–56, doi:10.1007/BF02464432, hdl: 1834/21257 , S2CID   189885665
  2. Bousquet, N.; Duchesne, T.; Rivest, L.-P. (2008). "Redefining the maximum sustainable yield for the Schaefer population model including multiplicative environmental noise" (PDF). Journal of Theoretical Biology. 254 (1): 65–75. Bibcode:2008JThBi.254...65B. doi:10.1016/j.jtbi.2008.04.025. PMID   18571675.
  3. Thorpe, R.B.; LeQuesne, W.J.F.; Luxford, F.; Collie, J.S.; Jennings, S. (2015). "Evaluation and management implications of uncertainty in a multispecies size-structured model of population and community responses to fishing". Methods in Ecology and Evolution. 6 (1): 49–58. doi:10.1111/2041-210X.12292. PMC   4390044 . PMID   25866615.
  4. 1 2 Russell, E. S. (1931). "Some theoretical Considerations on the "Overfishing" Problem". ICES Journal of Marine Science. 6 (1): 3–20. doi:10.1093/icesjms/6.1.3. ISSN   1054-3139.
  5. Hjort, J.; Jahn, G.; Ottestad, P. (1933). "The optimum catch". Hvalradets Skrifter. 7: 92–127.
  6. Graham, M. (1935). "Modern Theory of Exploiting a Fishery, and Application to North Sea Trawling". ICES Journal of Marine Science. 10 (3): 264–274. doi:10.1093/icesjms/10.3.264. ISSN   1054-3139.
  7. IATTC, Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission
  8. 1 2 3 4 Mace, P.M. (2001). "A new role for MSY in single-species and ecosystem approaches to fisheries stock assessment and management" (PDF). Fish and Fisheries. 2: 2–32. doi:10.1046/j.1467-2979.2001.00033.x.
  9. 1 2 Botsford, L.W.; Castilla, J.C.; Peterson, C.H. (1997). "The management of fisheries and marine ecosystems". Science. 277 (5325): 509–515. doi:10.1126/science.277.5325.509.
  10. 1 2 Larkin, P. A. (1977). "An epitaph for the concept of maximum sustained yield". Transactions of the American Fisheries Society. 106 (1): 1–11. doi:10.1577/1548-8659(1977)106<1:AEFTCO>2.0.CO;2. ISSN   0002-8487.
  11. Sissenwine, M.P. (1978). "Is MSY an adequate foundation for optimum yield?". Fisheries. 3 (6): 22–42. doi:10.1577/1548-8446(1978)003<0022:IMAAFF>2.0.CO;2.
  12. 1 2 Walters, C; Maguire, J (1996). "Lessons for stock assessment from the northern cod collapse". Reviews in Fish Biology and Fisheries. 6 (2): 125–137. doi:10.1007/bf00182340. S2CID   20224324.
  13. 1 2 3 4 5 Milner-Gulland and Mace 1998, pp. 14-17.
  14. 1 2 3 4 5 Jennings, S., Kaiser, M.J. and Reynolds, J.D. (2001), Marine Fisheries Ecology Blackwell Science Ltd. Malden, MA. ISBN   0-632-05098-5
  15. 1 2 3 4 5 Milner-Gulland, E.J., Mace, R. (1998), Conservation of biological resources Wiley-Blackwell. ISBN   978-0-86542-738-9.
  16. Bolden, E.G., Robinson, W.L. (1999), Wildlife ecology and management 4th ed. Prentice-Hall, Inc. Upper Saddle River, NJ. ISBN   0-13-840422-4
  17. 1 2 Reed, William J. (1980-01-01). "Optimum Age-Specific Harvesting in a Nonlinear Population Model". Biometrics. 36 (4): 579–593. doi:10.2307/2556112. JSTOR   2556112.
  18. Boucekkine, Raouf; Hritonenko, Natali; Yatsenko, Yuri (2013). Optimal Control of Age-structured Populations in Economy, Demography, and the Environment. Routledge. ISBN   978-1136920936.
  19. Getz, Wayne M. (1980-01-01). "The ultimate-sustainable-yield problem in nonlinear age-structured populations". Mathematical Biosciences. 48 (3–4): 279–292. doi:10.1016/0025-5564(80)90062-0. ISSN   0025-5564. Archived from the original on 2017-02-03. Retrieved 2017-01-28.
  20. Tahvonen, Olli (2009). "Optimal Harvesting of Age-structured Fish Populations". Marine Resource Economics. 24 (2): 147–169. doi:10.5950/0738-1360-24.2.147. S2CID   153448834.
  21. Holden, Matthew H.; Conrad, Jon M. (2015-11-01). "Optimal escapement in stage-structured fisheries with environmental stochasticity". Mathematical Biosciences. 269: 76–85. doi:10.1016/j.mbs.2015.08.021. PMID   26362229.
  22. National Research Council (NRC). 1998. Improving Fish Stock Assessments. National Academy Press, Washington, D.C.
  23. Clark, C.W. (1990), Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources, 2nd ed. Wiley-Interscience, New York
  24. National Marine Fisheries Service (NMFS). 1996. OUr Living Oceans: Report on the Status of U.S. Living Marine Resources 1995. NOAA Technical Memorandum NMFS0F/SPO-19. NMFS, Silver Springs, Md.
  25. 1 2 3 Townsend, C.R., Begon, M., and Harper, J.L. (2008), Essentials of Ecology Blackwell Publishing. ISBN   978-1-4051-5658-5
  26. Reed, William J (1979-12-01). "Optimal escapement levels in stochastic and deterministic harvesting models". Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 6 (4): 350–363. doi:10.1016/0095-0696(79)90014-7.
  27. Holden, Matthew H.; Ellner, Stephen P. (2016-07-01). "Human judgment vs. quantitative models for the management of ecological resources". Ecological Applications. 26 (5): 1553–1565. arXiv: 1603.04518 . doi:10.1890/15-1295. ISSN   1939-5582. PMID   27755756. S2CID   1279459.
  28. Maunder, M.N. (2008). "Maximum Sustainable Yield". Encyclopedia of Ecology. pp. 2292–2296. doi:10.1016/B978-008045405-4.00522-X. ISBN   9780080454054.
  29. Larkin PA (1977) "An epitaph for the concept of maximum sustained yield" [ permanent dead link ]Transactions of the American Fisheries Society, 106: 1–11.
  30. sciencemag.org Worm, Boris, et. a;. "Impacts of Biodiversity Loss on Ocean Ecosystem Services," Science, 3 November 2006.
  31. Christy, F.T., and Scott, A.D. (1965), The common Wealth in Ocean Fisheries, Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore
  32. 1 2 Clark, C.W. (1973). "The Economics of Overexploitation". Science. 118 (4100): 630–634. Bibcode:1973Sci...181..630C. doi:10.1126/science.181.4100.630. PMID   17736970. S2CID   30839110.
  33. FAO, Review of the State of World Marine Fishery Resources, FAO Technical Paper 335 (1994).
  34. Roberts, C. (2007), The Unnatural History of the Sea, Island Press. ISBN   978-1-59726-102-9
  35. Pauly, D. (1998). "Fishing Down Marine Food Webs". Science. 279 (5352): 860–863. Bibcode:1998Sci...279..860P. doi:10.1126/science.279.5352.860. ISSN   0036-8075. PMID   9452385.