Decentralization

Last updated

Decentralization or decentralisation is the process by which the activities of an organization, particularly those regarding planning and decision-making, are distributed or delegated away from a central, authoritative location or group and given to smaller factions within it. [1]

Contents

Concepts of decentralization have been applied to group dynamics and management science in private businesses and organizations, political science, law and public administration, technology, economics and money.

History

Alexis de Tocqueville Alexis de Tocqueville.jpg
Alexis de Tocqueville

The word "centralisation" came into use in France in 1794 as the post-Revolution French Directory leadership created a new government structure. The word "décentralisation" came into usage in the 1820s. [2] "Centralization" entered written English in the first third of the 1800s; [3] mentions of decentralization also first appear during those years. In the mid-1800s Tocqueville would write that the French Revolution began with "a push towards decentralization ... [but became,] in the end, an extension of centralization." [4] In 1863, retired French bureaucrat Maurice Block wrote an article called "Decentralization" for a French journal that reviewed the dynamics of government and bureaucratic centralization and recent French efforts at decentralization of government functions. [5]

Ideas of liberty and decentralization were carried to their logical conclusions during the 19th and 20th centuries by anti-state political activists calling themselves "anarchists", "libertarians", and even decentralists. Tocqueville was an advocate, writing: "Decentralization has, not only an administrative value but also a civic dimension since it increases the opportunities for citizens to take interest in public affairs; it makes them get accustomed to using freedom. And from the accumulation of these local, active, persnickety freedoms, is born the most efficient counterweight against the claims of the central government, even if it were supported by an impersonal, collective will." [6] Pierre-Joseph Proudhon (1809–1865), influential anarchist theorist [7] [8] wrote: "All my economic ideas as developed over twenty-five years can be summed up in the words: agricultural-industrial federation. All my political ideas boil down to a similar formula: political federation or decentralization." [9]

In the early 20th century, America's response to the centralization of economic wealth and political power was a decentralist movement. It blamed large-scale industrial production for destroying middle-class shop keepers and small manufacturers and promoted increased property ownership and a return to small scale living. The decentralist movement attracted Southern Agrarians like Robert Penn Warren, as well as journalist Herbert Agar. [10] New Left and libertarian individuals who identified with social, economic, and often political decentralism through the ensuing years included Ralph Borsodi, Wendell Berry, Paul Goodman, Carl Oglesby, Karl Hess, Donald Livingston, Kirkpatrick Sale (author of Human Scale), [11] Murray Bookchin, [12] Dorothy Day, [13] Senator Mark O. Hatfield, [14] Mildred J. Loomis [15] and Bill Kauffman. [16]

Decentralization was one of ten Megatrends identified in this best seller. Megatrendsbookcover.jpg
Decentralization was one of ten Megatrends identified in this best seller.

Leopold Kohr, author of the 1957 book The Breakdown of Nations – known for its statement "Whenever something is wrong, something is too big" – was a major influence on E. F. Schumacher, author of the 1973 bestseller Small Is Beautiful: A Study of Economics As If People Mattered . [17] [18] In the next few years a number of best-selling books promoted decentralization.

Daniel Bell's The Coming of Post-Industrial Society [4] discussed the need for decentralization and a "comprehensive overhaul of government structure to find the appropriate size and scope of units", as well as the need to detach functions from current state boundaries, creating regions based on functions like water, transport, education and economics which might have "different 'overlays' on the map." [19] [20] Alvin Toffler published Future Shock (1970) and The Third Wave (1980). Discussing the books in a later interview, Toffler said that industrial-style, centralized, top-down bureaucratic planning would be replaced by a more open, democratic, decentralized style which he called "anticipatory democracy". [21] Futurist John Naisbitt's 1982 book "Megatrends" was on The New York Times Best Seller list for more than two years and sold 14 million copies. [22] Naisbitt's book outlines 10 "megatrends", the fifth of which is from centralization to decentralization. [23] In 1996 David Osborne and Ted Gaebler had a best selling book Reinventing Government proposing decentralist public administration theories which became labeled the "New Public Management". [24]

Stephen Cummings wrote that decentralization became a "revolutionary megatrend" in the 1980s. [25] In 1983 Diana Conyers asked if decentralization was the "latest fashion" in development administration. [26] Cornell University's project on Restructuring Local Government states that decentralization refers to the "global trend" of devolving responsibilities to regional or local governments. [27] Robert J. Bennett's Decentralization, Intergovernmental Relations and Markets: Towards a Post-Welfare Agenda describes how after World War II governments pursued a centralized "welfarist" policy of entitlements which now has become a "post-welfare" policy of intergovernmental and market-based decentralization. [27]

In 1983, "Decentralization" was identified as one of the "Ten Key Values" of the Green Movement in the United States.

A 1999 United Nations Development Programme report stated:

"A large number of developing and transitional countries have embarked on some form of decentralization programmes. This trend is coupled with a growing interest in the role of civil society and the private sector as partners to governments in seeking new ways of service delivery ... Decentralization of governance and the strengthening of local governing capacity is in part also a function of broader societal trends. These include, for example, the growing distrust of government generally, the spectacular demise of some of the most centralized regimes in the world (especially the Soviet Union) and the emerging separatist demands that seem to routinely pop up in one or another part of the world. The movement toward local accountability and greater control over one's destiny is, however, not solely the result of the negative attitude towards central government. Rather, these developments, as we have already noted, are principally being driven by a strong desire for greater participation of citizens and private sector organizations in governance." [28]

Overview

Systems approach

Graphical comparison of centralized and decentralized system Decentralization.jpg
Graphical comparison of centralized and decentralized system

Those studying the goals and processes of implementing decentralization often use a systems theory approach, which according to the United Nations Development Programme report applies to the topic of decentralization "a whole systems perspective, including levels, spheres, sectors and functions and seeing the community level as the entry point at which holistic definitions of development goals are from the people themselves and where it is most practical to support them. It involves seeing multi-level frameworks and continuous, synergistic processes of interaction and iteration of cycles as critical for achieving wholeness in a decentralized system and for sustaining its development." [29]

However, it has been seen as part of a systems approach. Norman Johnson of Los Alamos National Laboratory wrote in a 1999 paper: "A decentralized system is where some decisions by the agents are made without centralized control or processing. An important property of agent systems is the degree of connectivity or connectedness between the agents, a measure global flow of information or influence. If each agent is connected (exchange states or influence) to all other agents, then the system is highly connected." [30]

University of California, Irvine's Institute for Software Research's "PACE" project is creating an "architectural style for trust management in decentralized applications." It adopted Rohit Khare's definition of decentralization: "A decentralized system is one which requires multiple parties to make their own independent decisions" and applies it to Peer-to-peer software creation, writing:

In such a decentralized system, there is no single centralized authority that makes decisions on behalf of all the parties. Instead each party, also called a peer, makes local autonomous decisions towards its individual goals which may possibly conflict with those of other peers. Peers directly interact with each other and share information or provide service to other peers. An open decentralized system is one in which the entry of peers is not regulated. Any peer can enter or leave the system at any time ... [31]

Goals

Decentralization in any area is a response to the problems of centralized systems. Decentralization in government, the topic most studied, has been seen as a solution to problems like economic decline, government inability to fund services and their general decline in performance of overloaded services, the demands of minorities for a greater say in local governance, the general weakening legitimacy of the public sector and global and international pressure on countries with inefficient, undemocratic, overly centralized systems. [32] The following four goals or objectives are frequently stated in various analyses of decentralization.

Participation

In decentralization, the principle of subsidiarity is often invoked. It holds that the lowest or least centralized authority that is capable of addressing an issue effectively should do so. According to one definition: "Decentralization, or decentralizing governance, refers to the restructuring or reorganization of authority so that there is a system of co-responsibility between institutions of governance at the central, regional and local levels according to the principle of subsidiarity, thus increasing the overall quality and effectiveness of the system of governance while increasing the authority and capacities of sub-national levels." [33]

Decentralization is often linked to concepts of participation in decision-making, democracy, equality and liberty from a higher authority. [34] [35] Decentralization enhances the democratic voice. [27] Theorists believe that local representative authorities with actual discretionary powers are the basis of decentralization that can lead to local efficiency, equity and development." [36] Columbia University's Earth Institute identified one of three major trends relating to decentralization: "increased involvement of local jurisdictions and civil society in the management of their affairs, with new forms of participation, consultation, and partnerships." [6]

Decentralization has been described as a "counterpoint to globalization [which] removes decisions from the local and national stage to the global sphere of multi-national or non-national interests. Decentralization brings decision-making back to the sub-national levels". Decentralization strategies must account for the interrelations of global, regional, national, sub-national, and local levels. [37]

Diversity

Norman L. Johnson writes that diversity plays an important role in decentralized systems like ecosystems, social groups, large organizations, political systems. "Diversity is defined to be unique properties of entities, agents, or individuals that are not shared by the larger group, population, structure. Decentralized is defined as a property of a system where the agents have some ability to operate "locally." Both decentralization and diversity are necessary attributes to achieve the self-organizing properties of interest." [30]

Advocates of political decentralization hold that greater participation by better informed diverse interests in society will lead to more relevant decisions than those made only by authorities on the national level. [38] Decentralization has been described as a response to demands for diversity. [6] [39]

Efficiency

In business, decentralization leads to a management by results philosophy which focuses on definite objectives to be achieved by unit results. [40] Decentralization of government programs is said to increase efficiency – and effectiveness – due to reduction of congestion in communications, quicker reaction to unanticipated problems, improved ability to deliver services, improved information about local conditions, and more support from beneficiaries of programs. [41]

Firms may prefer decentralization because it ensures efficiency by making sure that managers closest to the local information make decisions and in a more timely fashion; that their taking responsibility frees upper management for long term strategics rather than day-to-day decision-making; that managers have hands on training to prepare them to move up the management hierarchy; that managers are motivated by having the freedom to exercise their own initiative and creativity; that managers and divisions are encouraged to prove that they are profitable, instead of allowing their failures to be masked by the overall profitability of the company. [42]

The same principles can be applied to the government. Decentralization promises to enhance efficiency through both inter-governmental competitions with market features and fiscal discipline which assigns tax and expenditure authority to the lowest level of government possible. It works best where members of the subnational government have strong traditions of democracy, accountability, and professionalism. [27]

Conflict resolution

Economic and/or political decentralization can help prevent or reduce conflict because they reduce actual or perceived inequities between various regions or between a region and the central government. [43] Dawn Brancati finds that political decentralization reduces intrastate conflict unless politicians create political parties that mobilize minority and even extremist groups to demand more resources and power within national governments. However, the likelihood this will be done depends on factors like how democratic transitions happen and features like a regional party's proportion of legislative seats, a country's number of regional legislatures, elector procedures, and the order in which national and regional elections occur. Brancati holds that decentralization can promote peace if it encourages statewide parties to incorporate regional demands and limit the power of regional parties. [44]

Processes

Initiation

The processes by which entities move from a more to a less centralized state vary. They can be initiated from the centers of authority ("top-down") or from individuals, localities or regions ("bottom-up"), [45] or from a "mutually desired" combination of authorities and localities working together. [46] Bottom-up decentralization usually stresses political values like local responsiveness and increased participation and tends to increase political stability. Top-down decentralization may be motivated by the desire to "shift deficits downwards" and find more resources to pay for services or pay off government debt. [45] Some hold that decentralization should not be imposed, but done in a respectful manner. [47]

Appropriate size

Gauging the appropriate size or scale of decentralized units has been studied in relation to the size of sub-units of hospitals [48] and schools, [32] road networks, [49] administrative units in business [50] and public administration, and especially town and city governmental areas and decision-making bodies. [51] [52]

In creating planned communities ("new towns"), it is important to determine the appropriate population and geographical size. While in earlier years small towns were considered appropriate, by the 1960s, 60,000 inhabitants was considered the size necessary to support a diversified job market and an adequate shopping center and array of services and entertainment. Appropriate size of governmental units for revenue raising also is a consideration. [53]

Even in bioregionalism, which seeks to reorder many functions and even the boundaries of governments according to physical and environmental features, including watershed boundaries and soil and terrain characteristics, appropriate size must be considered. The unit may be larger than many decentralist-bioregionalists prefer. [54]

Inadvertent or silent

Decentralization ideally happens as a careful, rational, and orderly process, but it often takes place during times of economic and political crisis, the fall of a regime and the resultant power struggles. Even when it happens slowly, there is a need for experimentation, testing, adjusting, and replicating successful experiments in other contexts. There is no one blueprint for decentralization since it depends on the initial state of a country and the power and views of political interests and whether they support or oppose decentralization. [55]

Decentralization usually is a conscious process based on explicit policies. However, it may occur as "silent decentralization" in the absence of reforms as changes in networks, policy emphasize and resource availability lead inevitably to a more decentralized system. [56]

Asymmetry

Decentralization may be uneven and "asymmetric" given any one country's population, political, ethnic and other forms of diversity. In many countries, political, economic and administrative responsibilities may be decentralized to the larger urban areas, while rural areas are administered by the central government. Decentralization of responsibilities to provinces may be limited only to those provinces or states which want or are capable of handling responsibility. Some privatization may be more appropriate to an urban than a rural area; some types of privatization may be more appropriate for some states and provinces but not others. [57]

Determinants

The academic literature frequently mentions the following factors as determinants of decentralization: [58]

In government policy

Historians have described the history of governments and empires in terms of centralization and decentralization. In his 1910 The History of Nations Henry Cabot Lodge wrote that Persian king Darius I (550–486 BC) was a master of organization and "for the first time in history centralization becomes a political fact." He also noted that this contrasted with the decentralization of Ancient Greece. [59] Since the 1980s a number of scholars have written about cycles of centralization and decentralization. Stephen K. Sanderson wrote that over the last 4000 years chiefdoms and actual states have gone through sequences of centralization and decentralization of economic, political and social power. [60] Yildiz Atasoy writes this process has been going on "since the Stone Age" through not just chiefdoms and states, but empires and today's "hegemonic core states". [61] Christopher K. Chase-Dunn and Thomas D. Hall review other works that detail these cycles, including works which analyze the concept of core elites which compete with state accumulation of wealth and how their "intra-ruling-class competition accounts for the rise and fall of states" and their phases of centralization and decentralization. [62]

Rising government expenditures, poor economic performance and the rise of free market-influenced ideas have convinced governments to decentralize their operations, to induce competition within their services, to contract out to private firms operating in the market, and to privatize some functions and services entirely. [63]

East Province, Rwanda, created in 2006 as part of a government decentralization process East Province districts.png
East Province, Rwanda, created in 2006 as part of a government decentralization process

Government decentralization has both political and administrative aspects. Its decentralization may be territorial, moving power from a central city to other localities, and it may be functional, moving decision-making from the top administrator of any branch of government to lower level officials, or divesting of the function entirely through privatization. [64] It has been called the "new public management" which has been described as decentralization, management by objectives, contracting out, competition within government and consumer orientation. [65]

Political

Political decentralization signifies a reduction in the authority of national governments over policy-making. This process is accomplished by the institution of reforms that either delegate a certain degree of meaningful decision-making autonomy to sub-national tiers of government, [66] or grant citizens the right to elect lower-level officials, like local or regional representatives. [67] Depending on the country, this may require constitutional or statutory reforms, the development of new political parties, increased power for legislatures, the creation of local political units, and encouragement of advocacy groups. [38]

A national government may decide to decentralize its authority and responsibilities for a variety of reasons. Decentralization reforms may occur for administrative reasons, when government officials decide that certain responsibilities and decisions would be handled best at the regional or local level. In democracies, traditionally conservative parties include political decentralization as a directive in their platforms because rightist parties tend to advocate for a decrease in the role of central government. There is also strong evidence to support the idea that government stability increases the probability of political decentralization, since instability brought on by gridlock between opposing parties in legislatures often impedes a government's overall ability to enact sweeping reforms. [66]

The rise of regional ethnic parties in the national politics of parliamentary democracies is also heavily associated with the implementation of decentralization reforms. [66] Ethnic parties may endeavor to transfer more autonomy to their respective regions, and as a partisan strategy, ruling parties within the central government may cooperate by establishing regional assemblies in order to curb the rise of ethnic parties in national elections. [66] This phenomenon famously occurred in 1999, when the United Kingdom's Labour Party appealed to Scottish constituents by creating a semi-autonomous Scottish Parliament in order to neutralize the threat from the increasingly popular Scottish National Party at the national level. [66]

In addition to increasing the administrative efficacy of government and endowing citizens with more power, there are many projected advantages to political decentralization. Individuals who take advantage of their right to elect local and regional authorities have been shown to have more positive attitudes toward politics, [68] and increased opportunities for civic decision-making through participatory democracy mechanisms like public consultations and participatory budgeting are believed to help legitimize government institutions in the eyes of marginalized groups. [69] Moreover, political decentralization is perceived as a valid means of protecting marginalized communities at a local level from the detrimental aspects of development and globalization driven by the state, like the degradation of local customs, codes, and beliefs. [70] In his 2013 book, Democracy and Political Ignorance , George Mason University law professor Ilya Somin argued that political decentralization in a federal democracy confronts the widespread issue of political ignorance by allowing citizens to engage in foot voting, or moving to other jurisdictions with more favorable laws. [71] He cites the mass migration of over one million southern-born African Americans to the North or the West to evade discriminatory Jim Crow laws in the late 19th century and early 20th century. [71]

The European Union follows the principle of subsidiarity, which holds that decision-making should be made by the most local competent authority. The EU should decide only on enumerated issues that a local or member state authority cannot address themselves. Furthermore, enforcement is exclusively the domain of member states. In Finland, the Centre Party explicitly supports decentralization. For example, government departments have been moved from the capital Helsinki to the provinces. The centre supports substantial subsidies that limit potential economic and political centralization to Helsinki. [72]

Political decentralization does not come without its drawbacks. A study by Fan concludes that there is an increase in corruption and rent-seeking when there are more vertical tiers in the government, as well as when there are higher levels of subnational government employment. [73] Other studies warn of high-level politicians that may intentionally deprive regional and local authorities of power and resources when conflicts arise. [70] In order to combat these negative forces, experts believe that political decentralization should be supplemented with other conflict management mechanisms like power-sharing, particularly in regions with ethnic tensions. [69]

Administrative

Four major forms of administrative decentralization have been described. [74] [75]

Fiscal

Fiscal decentralization means decentralizing revenue raising and/or expenditure of moneys to a lower level of government while maintaining financial responsibility. [74] While this process usually is called fiscal federalism, it may be relevant to unitary, federal, or confederal governments. Fiscal federalism also concerns the "vertical imbalances" where the central government gives too much or too little money to the lower levels. It actually can be a way of increasing central government control of lower levels of government, if it is not linked to other kinds of responsibilities and authority. [79] [80] [81]

Fiscal decentralization can be achieved through user fees, user participation through monetary or labor contributions, expansion of local property or sales taxes, intergovernmental transfers of central government tax monies to local governments through transfer payments or grants, and authorization of municipal borrowing with national government loan guarantees. Transfers of money may be given conditionally with instructions or unconditionally without them. [74] [82]

Market

Market decentralization can be done through privatization of public owned functions and businesses, as described briefly above. But it also is done through deregulation, the abolition of restrictions on businesses competing with government services, for example, postal services, schools, garbage collection. Even as private companies and corporations have worked to have such services contracted out to or privatized by them, others have worked to have these turned over to non-profit organizations or associations. [74]

From the 1970s to the 1990s, there was deregulation of some industries, like banking, trucking, airlines and telecommunications, which resulted generally in more competition and lower prices. [83] According to the Cato Institute, an American libertarian think-tank, in some cases deregulation in some aspects of an industry were offset by increased regulation in other aspects, the electricity industry being a prime example. [84] For example, in banking, Cato Institute believes some deregulation allowed banks to compete across state lines, increasing consumer choice, while an actual increase in regulators and regulations forced banks to make loans to individuals incapable of repaying them, leading eventually to the financial crisis of 2007–2008. [85] [ unreliable source? ]

One example of economic decentralization, which is based on a libertarian socialist model, is decentralized economic planning. Decentralized planning is a type of economic system in which decision-making is distributed amongst various economic agents or localized within production agents. An example of this method in practice is in Kerala, India which experimented in 1996 with the People's Plan campaign. [86]

Emmanuelle Auriol and Michel Benaim write about the "comparative benefits" of decentralization versus government regulation in the setting of standards. They find that while there may be a need for public regulation if public safety is at stake, private creation of standards usually is better because "regulators or 'experts' might misrepresent consumers' tastes and needs." As long as companies are averse to incompatible standards, standards will be created that satisfy needs of a modern economy. [87]

Environmental

Central governments themselves may own large tracts of land and control the forest, water, mineral, wildlife and other resources they contain. They may manage them through government operations or leasing them to private businesses; or they may neglect them to be exploited by individuals or groups who defy non-enforced laws against exploitation. It also may control most private land through land-use, zoning, environmental and other regulations. [88] Selling off or leasing lands can be profitable for governments willing to relinquish control, but such programs can face public scrutiny because of fear of a loss of heritage or of environmental damage. Devolution of control to regional or local governments has been found to be an effective way of dealing with these concerns. [89] [90] Such decentralization has happened in India [91] and other developing nations. [92]

In economic ideology

Libertarian socialism

Pierre Joseph Proudhon, anarchist theorist who advocated for a decentralist non-state system which he called "federalism" Portrait of Pierre Joseph Proudhon 1865.jpg
Pierre Joseph Proudhon, anarchist theorist who advocated for a decentralist non-state system which he called "federalism"

Libertarian socialism is a political philosophy that promotes a non-hierarchical, non-bureaucratic society without private property in the means of production. Libertarian socialists believe in converting present-day private productive property into common or public goods. [94] Libertarian socialism is opposed to coercive forms of social organization. It promotes free association in place of government and opposes the various social relations of capitalism, such as wage slavery. [95] The term libertarian socialism is used by some socialists to differentiate their philosophy from state socialism, [96] [97] and by some as a synonym for left anarchism. [98] [99] [100]

Accordingly, libertarian socialists believe that "the exercise of power in any institutionalized form – whether economic, political, religious, or sexual – brutalizes both the wielder of power and the one over whom it is exercised". [101] Libertarian socialists generally place their hopes in decentralized means of direct democracy such as libertarian municipalism, citizens' assemblies, or workers' councils. [102] Libertarian socialists are strongly critical of coercive institutions, which often leads them to reject the legitimacy of the state in favor of anarchism. [103] Adherents propose achieving this through decentralization of political and economic power, usually involving the socialization of most large-scale private property and enterprise (while retaining respect for personal property). Libertarian socialism tends to deny the legitimacy of most forms of economically significant private property, viewing capitalist property relations as forms of domination that are antagonistic to individual freedom. [104] [105]

Political philosophies commonly described as libertarian socialist include most varieties of anarchism (especially anarcho-communism, anarchist collectivism, anarcho-syndicalism, [106] social anarchism and mutualism) [107] as well as autonomism, communalism, participism, libertarian Marxist philosophies such as council communism and Luxemburgism, [108] and some versions of utopian socialism [109] and individualist anarchism. [110] [111] [112] For Murray Bookchin "In the modern world, anarchism first appeared as a movement of the peasantry and yeomanry against declining feudal institutions. In Germany its foremost spokesman during the Peasant Wars was Thomas Muenzer; in England, Gerrard Winstanley, a leading participant in the Digger movement. The concepts held by Muenzer and Winstanley were superbly attuned to the needs of their time – a historical period when the majority of the population lived in the countryside and when the most militant revolutionary forces came from an agrarian world. It would be painfully academic to argue whether Muenzer and Winstanley could have achieved their ideals. What is of real importance is that they spoke to their time; their anarchist concepts followed naturally from the rural society that furnished the bands of the peasant armies in Germany and the New Model in England." [113] The term "anarchist" first entered the English language in 1642, during the English Civil War, as a term of abuse, used by Royalists against their Roundhead opponents. [114] By the time of the French Revolution some, such as the Enragés , began to use the term positively, [115] in opposition to Jacobin centralisation of power, seeing "revolutionary government" as oxymoronic. [114] By the turn of the 19th century, the English word "anarchism" had lost its initial negative connotation. [114]

For Pierre-Joseph Proudhon, mutualism involved creating "industrial democracy", a system where workplaces would be "handed over to democratically organised workers' associations . . . We want these associations to be models for agriculture, industry and trade, the pioneering core of that vast federation of companies and societies woven into the common cloth of the democratic social Republic." [116] He urged "workers to form themselves into democratic societies, with equal conditions for all members, on pain of a relapse into feudalism." This would result in "Capitalistic and proprietary exploitation, stopped everywhere, the wage system abolished, equal and just exchange guaranteed." [117] Workers would no longer sell their labour to a capitalist but rather work for themselves in co-operatives. Anarcho-communism calls for a confederal form in relationships of mutual aid and free association between communes as an alternative to the centralism of the nation-state. Peter Kropotkin thus suggested that "Representative government has accomplished its historical mission; it has given a mortal blow to court-rule; and by its debates it has awakened public interest in public questions. But to see in it the government of the future socialist society is to commit a gross error. Each economic phase of life implies its own political phase; and it is impossible to touch the very basis of the present economic life-private property – without a corresponding change in the very basis of the political organization. Life already shows in which direction the change will be made. Not in increasing the powers of the State, but in resorting to free organization and free federation in all those branches which are now considered as attributes of the State." [118] When the First Spanish Republic was established in 1873 after the abdication of King Amadeo, the first president, Estanislao Figueras, named Francesc Pi i Margall Minister of the Interior. His acquaintance with Proudhon enabled Pi to warm relations between the Republicans and the socialists in Spain. Pi i Margall became the principal translator of Proudhon's works into Spanish [119] and later briefly became president of Spain in 1873 while being the leader of the Democratic Republican Federal Party. According to George Woodcock "These translations were to have a profound and lasting effect on the development of Spanish anarchism after 1870, but before that time Proudhonian ideas, as interpreted by Pi, already provided much of the inspiration for the federalist movement which sprang up in the early 1860s." [120] According to the Encyclopædia Britannica "During the Spanish revolution of 1873, Pi y Margall attempted to establish a decentralized, cantonalist political system on Proudhonian lines." [121]

To date, the best-known examples of an anarchist communist society (i.e., established around the ideas as they exist today and achieving worldwide attention and knowledge in the historical canon), are the anarchist territories during the Spanish Revolution [122] and the Makhnovshchina during the Russian Revolution. Through the efforts and influence of the Spanish anarchists during the Spanish Revolution within the Spanish Civil War, starting in 1936 anarchist communism existed in most of Aragon, parts of the Levante and Andalusia, as well as in the stronghold of Anarchist Catalonia before being crushed by the combined forces of the regime that won the war, Hitler, Mussolini, Spanish Communist Party repression (backed by the USSR) as well as economic and armaments blockades from the capitalist countries and the Second Spanish Republic itself. [123] During the Russian Revolution, anarchists such as Nestor Makhno worked to create and defend – through the Revolutionary Insurgent Army of Ukraine – anarchist communism in Ukraine from 1919 before being conquered by the Bolsheviks in 1921. Several libertarian socialists, notably Noam Chomsky among others, believe that anarchism shares much in common with certain variants of Marxism (see libertarian Marxism) such as the council communism of Marxist Anton Pannekoek. In Chomsky's Notes on Anarchism , [124] he suggests the possibility "that some form of council communism is the natural form of revolutionary socialism in an industrial society. It reflects the belief that democracy is severely limited when the industrial system is controlled by any form of autocratic elite, whether of owners, managers, and technocrats, a 'vanguard' party, or a State bureaucracy." [124]

Free market

Free market ideas popular in the 19th century such as those of Adam Smith returned to prominence in the 1970s and 1980s. Austrian School economist Friedrich von Hayek argued that free markets themselves are decentralized systems where outcomes are produced without explicit agreement or coordination by individuals who use prices as their guide. [125] Eleanor Doyle writes that "[e]conomic decision-making in free markets is decentralized across all the individuals dispersed in each market and is synchronized or coordinated by the price system," and holds that an individual right to property is part of this decentralized system. [126] Criticizing central government control, Hayek wrote in The Road to Serfdom :

There would be no difficulty about efficient control or planning were conditions so simple that a single person or board could effectively survey all the relevant facts. It is only as the factors which have to be taken into account become so numerous that it is impossible to gain a synoptic view of them that decentralization becomes imperative. [127]

According to Bruce M. Owen, this does not mean that all firms themselves have to be equally decentralized. He writes: "markets allocate resources through arms-length transactions among decentralized actors. Much of the time, markets work very efficiently, but there is a variety of conditions under which firms do better. Hence, goods and services are produced and sold by firms with various degrees of horizontal and vertical integration." Additionally, he writes that the "economic incentive to expand horizontally or vertically is usually, but not always, compatible with the social interest in maximizing long-run consumer welfare." [128]

It is often claimed that free markets and private property generate centralized monopolies and other ills; free market advocates counter with the argument that government is the source of monopoly. [129] Historian Gabriel Kolko in his book The Triumph of Conservatism argued that in the first decade of the 20th century businesses were highly decentralized and competitive, with new businesses constantly entering existing industries. In his view, there was no trend towards concentration and monopolization. While there were a wave of mergers of companies trying to corner markets, they found there was too much competition to do so. According to Kolko, this was also true in banking and finance, which saw decentralization as leading to instability as state and local banks competed with the big New York City firms. He argues that, as a result, the largest firms turned to the power of the state and worked with leaders like United States Presidents Theodore Roosevelt, William H. Taft and Woodrow Wilson to pass as "progressive reforms" centralizing laws like The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 that gave control of the monetary system to the wealthiest bankers; the formation of monopoly "public utilities" that made competition with those monopolies illegal; federal inspection of meat packers biased against small companies; extending Interstate Commerce Commission to regulating telephone companies and keeping rates high to benefit AT&T; and using the Sherman Antitrust Act against companies which might combine to threaten larger or monopoly companies. [130] [131] D. T. Armentano, writing for the Cato Institute, argues that when government licensing, franchises, and other legal restrictions create monopoly and protect companies from open competition, deregulation is the solution. [132]

Author and activist Jane Jacobs's influential 1961 book The Death and Life of American Cities criticized large-scale redevelopment projects which were part of government-planned decentralization of population and businesses to suburbs. She believed it destroyed cities' economies and impoverished remaining residents. [133] Her 1980 book The Question of Separatism: Quebec and the Struggle over Sovereignty supported secession of Quebec from Canada. [134] Her 1984 book Cities and the Wealth of Nations proposed a solution to the problems faced by cities whose economies were being ruined by centralized national governments: decentralization through the "multiplication of sovereignties", meaning an acceptance of the right of cities to secede from the larger nation states that were greatly limiting their ability to produce wealth. [135] [136]

In the organizational structure of a firm

In managerial economics, the principal-agent problem is a challenge faced by every firm. [137] In response to these incentive and information conflicts, a firm can either centralize their organizational structure by concentrating decision-making to upper management, or decentralize their organizational structure by delegating authority throughout the organization. [138] The delegation of authority comes with a basic trade-off: while it can increase efficiency and information flow, the central authority consequentially suffers a loss of control. [139] However, through creating an environment of trust and allocating authority formally in the firm, coupled with a stronger rule of law in the geographical location of the firm, the negative consequences of the trade-off can be minimized. [140]

In having a decentralized organizational structure, a firm can remain agile to external shocks and competing trends. Decision-making in a centralized organization can face information flow inefficiencies and barriers to effective communication which decreases the speed and accuracy in which decisions are made. A decentralized firm is said to hold greater flexibility given the efficiency in which it can analyze information and implement relevant outcomes. [141] Additionally, having decision-making power spread across different areas allows for local knowledge to inform decisions, increasing their relevancy and implementational effectiveness. [142] In the process of developing new products or services, the decentralization enable the firm gain advantages of closely meet particular division's needs. [143]

Decentralization also impacts human resource management. The high level of individual agency that workers experience within a decentralized firm can create job enrichment. Studies have shown this enhances the development of new ideas and innovations given the sense of involvement that comes from responsibility. [144] The impacts of decentralization on innovation are furthered by the ease of information flow that comes from this organizational structure. With increased knowledge sharing, workers are more able to use relevant information to inform decision-making. [145] These benefits are enhanced in firms with skill-intensive environments. Skilled workers are more able to analyze information, they pose less risk of information duplication given increased communication abilities, and the productivity cost of multi-tasking is lower. These outcomes of decentralizion make it a particularly effective organizational structure for entrepreneurial and competitive firm environments, such as start-up companies. The flexibility, efficiency of information flow and higher worker autonomy complement the rapid growth and innovation seen in successful start up companies. [146]

In technology and the internet

The Living Machine installation in the lobby of the Port of Portland headquarters which was completed and ready for occupation May 2010. The decentralized wastewater reuse system contributed to the headquarter's certification as a LEED Platinum building by the U.S. Green Building Council. Living Machine at Port of Portland-interior.jpg
The Living Machine installation in the lobby of the Port of Portland headquarters which was completed and ready for occupation May 2010. The decentralized wastewater reuse system contributed to the headquarter's certification as a LEED Platinum building by the U.S. Green Building Council.

Technological decentralization can be defined as a shift from concentrated to distributed modes of production and consumption of goods and services. [147] Generally, such shifts are accompanied by transformations in technology and different technologies are applied for either system. Technology includes tools, materials, skills, techniques and processes by which goals are accomplished in the public and private spheres. Concepts of decentralization of technology are used throughout all types of technology, including especially information technology and appropriate technology.

Technologies often mentioned as best implemented in a decentralized manner, include: water purification, delivery and waste water disposal, [148] [149] agricultural technology [150] and energy technology. [151] [152] Advancing technology may allow decentralized, privatized and free market solutions for what have been public services, such utilities producing and/or delivering power, water, mail, telecommunications and services like consumer product safety, money and banking, medical licensing and detection and metering technologies for highways, parking, and auto emissions. [153] [ clarification needed ] However, in terms of technology, a clear distinction between fully centralized or decentralized technical solutions is often not possible and therefore finding an optimal degree of centralization difficult from an infrastructure planning perspective. [154]

Information technology

Information technology encompasses computers and computer networks, as well as information distribution technologies such as television and telephones. The whole computer industry of computer hardware, software, electronics, internet, telecommunications equipment, e-commerce and computer services are included. [155]

Executives and managers face a constant tension between centralizing and decentralizing information technology for their organizations. They must find the right balance of centralizing which lowers costs and allows more control by upper management, and decentralizing which allows sub-units and users more control. This will depend on analysis of the specific situation. Decentralization is particularly applicable to business or management units which have a high level of independence, complicated products and customers, and technology less relevant to other units. [156]

Information technology applied to government communications with citizens, often called e-Government, is supposed to support decentralization and democratization. Various forms have been instituted in most nations worldwide. [157]

The internet is an example of an extremely decentralized network, having no owners at all (although some have argued that this is less the case in recent years [158] ). "No one is in charge of internet, and everyone is." As long as they follow a certain minimal number of rules, anyone can be a service provider or a user. Voluntary boards establish protocols, but cannot stop anyone from developing new ones. [159] Other examples of open source or decentralized movements are Wikis which allow users to add, modify, or delete content via the internet. [160] Wikipedia has been described as decentralized (although it is a centralized web site, with a single entity operating the servers). [161] Smartphones have been described as being an important part of the decentralizing effects of smaller and cheaper computers worldwide. [162]

Decentralization continues throughout the industry, for example as the decentralized architecture of wireless routers installed in homes and offices supplement and even replace phone companies' relatively centralized long-range cell towers. [163]

Inspired by system and cybernetics theorists like Norbert Wiener, Marshall McLuhan and Buckminster Fuller, in the 1960s Stewart Brand started the Whole Earth Catalog and later computer networking efforts to bring Silicon Valley computer technologists and entrepreneurs together with countercultural ideas. This resulted in ideas like personal computing, virtual communities and the vision of an "electronic frontier" which would be a more decentralized, egalitarian and free-market libertarian society. Related ideas coming out of Silicon Valley included the free software and creative commons movements which produced visions of a "networked information economy". [164]

Because human interactions in cyberspace transcend physical geography, there is a necessity for new theories in legal and other rule-making systems to deal with decentralized decision-making processes in such systems. For example, what rules should apply to conduct on the global digital network and who should set them? The laws of which nations govern issues of internet transactions (like seller disclosure requirements or definitions of "fraud"), copyright and trademark? [165]

Decentralized computing

Decentralized computing is the allocation of resources, both hardware and software, to each individual workstation, or office location. In contrast, centralized computing exists when the majority of functions are carried out, or obtained from a remote centralized location. Decentralized computing is a trend in modern-day business environments. This is the opposite of centralized computing, which was prevalent during the early days of computers. A decentralized computer system has many benefits over a conventional centralized network. [166] Desktop computers have advanced so rapidly, that their potential performance far exceeds the requirements of most business applications. This results in most desktop computers remaining idle (in relation to their full potential). A decentralized system can use the potential of these systems to maximize efficiency. However, it is debatable whether these networks increase overall effectiveness.

All computers have to be updated individually with new software, unlike a centralized computer system. Decentralized systems still enable file sharing and all computers can share peripherals such as printers and scanners as well as modems, allowing all the computers in the network to connect to the internet.

A collection of decentralized computers systems are components of a larger computer network, held together by local stations of equal importance and capability. These systems are capable of running independently of each other.

Centralization and re-decentralization of the Internet

The New Yorker reports that although the Internet was originally decentralized, by 2013 it had become less so: "a staggering percentage of communications flow through a small set of corporations – and thus, under the profound influence of those companies and other institutions [...] One solution, espoused by some programmers, is to make the Internet more like it used to be – less centralized and more distributed." [158]

Examples of projects that attempt to contribute to the re-decentralization of the Internet include ArkOS, Diaspora, FreedomBox, IndieWeb, Namecoin, SAFE Network, twtxt and ZeroNet as well as advocacy group Redecentralize.org, which provides support for projects that aim to make the Web less centralized. [158]

In an interview with BBC Radio 5 Live one of the co-founders of Redecentralize.org explained that:

"As we've gone on there's been more and more internet traffic focused through particular nodes such as Google or Facebook. [...] Centralised services that hold all the user data and host it themselves have become increasingly popular because that business model has worked. As the Internet has become more mass market, people are not necessarily willing or knowledgable to host it themselves, so where that hosting is outsourced it's become the default, which allows a centralization of power and a centralization of data that I think is worrying." [167]

Blockchain technology

In blockchain, decentralization refers to the transfer of control and decision-making from a centralized entity (individual, organization, or group thereof) to a distributed network. Decentralized networks strive to reduce the level of trust that participants must place in one another, and deter their ability to exert authority or control over one another in ways that degrade the functionality of the network. [168] This is seen as having the potential to create new ways of doing business in the finance industry. [169]

Cryptocurrencies use cryptographic proofs such as proof of work (e.g. Bitcoin) or proof of stake (e.g. Cardano) as a means of establishing decentralized consensus. Academic researchers are examining ways of measuring the level of decentralization in blockchain systems, by taking into account hardware, software, the network, consensus mechanism, economics (tokenomics), application interfaces, how the blockchain is managed over time (governance) and geographical distribution. [170]

Decentralized protocols, applications, and ledgers (used in Web3 [171] [172] ) could be more difficult for governments to regulate, similar to difficulties regulating BitTorrent (which is not a blockchain technology). [173] [174]

Appropriate technology

"Appropriate technology", originally described as "intermediate technology" by economist E. F. Schumacher in Small Is Beautiful: A Study of Economics As If People Mattered , is generally recognized as encompassing technologies that are small-scale, decentralized, labor-intensive, energy-efficient, environmentally sound, and locally controlled. [175] [ better source needed ]

Criticism

Factors hindering decentralization include weak local administrative or technical capacity, which may result in inefficient or ineffective services; inadequate financial resources available to perform new local responsibilities, especially in the start-up phase when they are most needed; or inequitable distribution of resources. [176] Decentralization can make national policy coordination too complex; it may allow local elites to capture functions; local cooperation may be undermined by any distrust between private and public sectors; decentralization may result in higher enforcement costs and conflict for resources if there is no higher level of authority. [177] Additionally, decentralization may not be as efficient for standardized, routine, network-based services, as opposed to those that need more complicated inputs. If there is a loss of economies of scale in procurement of labor or resources, the expense of decentralization can rise, even as central governments lose control over financial resources. [74]

Other challenges, and even dangers, include the possibility that corrupt local elites can capture regional or local power centers, while constituents lose representation; patronage politics will become rampant and civil servants feel compromised; further necessary decentralization can be stymied; incomplete information and hidden decision-making can occur up and down the hierarchies; centralized power centers can find reasons to frustrate decentralization and bring power back to themselves.[ citation needed ]

It has been noted that while decentralization may increase "productive efficiency" it may undermine "allocative efficiency" by making redistribution of wealth more difficult. Decentralization will cause greater disparities between rich and poor regions, especially during times of crisis when the national government may not be able to help regions needing it. [178]

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Anarcho-capitalism</span> Political philosophy and economic theory

Anarcho-capitalism is an anti-statist, libertarian political philosophy and economic theory that seeks to abolish centralized states in favor of stateless societies with systems of private property enforced by private agencies, based on concepts such as the non-aggression principle, free markets and self-ownership. Anarcho-capitalist philosophy extends the concept of ownership to include control of private property as part of the self, and, in some cases, control of other people as private property. In the absence of statute, anarcho-capitalists hold that society tends to contractually self-regulate and civilize through participation in the free market, which they describe as a voluntary society involving the voluntary exchange of goods and services. In a theoretical anarcho-capitalist society the system of private property would still exist, as it would be enforced by private defense agencies and/or insurance companies that were selected by property owners, whose ownership rights or claims would be enforced by private defence agencies and/or insurance companies. These agencies or companies would operate competitively in a market and fulfill the roles of courts and the police, similar to a state apparatus. Some anarcho-capitalist authors have argued that slavery is compatible with anarcho-capitalist ideals.

A planned economy is a type of economic system where the distribution of goods and services or the investment, production and the allocation of capital goods takes place according to economic plans that are either economy-wide or limited to a category of goods and services. A planned economy may use centralized, decentralized, participatory or Soviet-type forms of economic planning. The level of centralization or decentralization in decision-making and participation depends on the specific type of planning mechanism employed.

Individualist anarchism is the branch of anarchism that emphasizes the individual and their will over external determinants such as groups, society, traditions, and ideological systems. Although usually contrasted with social anarchism, both individualist and social anarchism have influenced each other. Mutualism, an economic theory sometimes considered a synthesis of communism and property, has been considered individualist anarchism and other times part of social anarchism. Many anarcho-communists regard themselves as radical individualists, seeing anarcho-communism as the best social system for the realization of individual freedom. Some anarcho-capitalists claim anarcho-capitalism is part of the individualist anarchist tradition, while others disagree and claim individualist anarchism is only part of the socialist movement and part of the libertarian socialist tradition. Economically, while European individualist anarchists are pluralists who advocate anarchism without adjectives and synthesis anarchism, ranging from anarcho-communist to mutualist economic types, most American individualist anarchists of the 19th century advocated mutualism, a libertarian socialist form of market socialism, or a free-market socialist form of classical economics. Individualist anarchists are opposed to property that violates the entitlement theory of justice, that is, gives privilege due to unjust acquisition or exchange, and thus is exploitative, seeking to "destroy the tyranny of capital, — that is, of property" by mutual credit.

Individualism is the moral stance, political philosophy, ideology and social outlook that emphasizes the intrinsic worth of the individual. Individualists promote realizing one's goals and desires, valuing independence and self-reliance, and advocating that the interests of the individual should gain precedence over the state or a social group, while opposing external interference upon one's own interests by society or institutions such as the government. Individualism makes the individual its focus, and so starts "with the fundamental premise that the human individual is of primary importance in the struggle for liberation".

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Anti-capitalism</span> Political ideology and movement opposed to capitalism

Anti-capitalism is a political ideology and movement encompassing a variety of attitudes and ideas that oppose capitalism. In this sense, anti-capitalists are those who wish to replace capitalism with another type of economic system, such as socialism or communism.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Peter Kropotkin</span> Russian anarchist (1842–1921)

Pyotr Alexeyevich Kropotkin was a Russian anarchist and geographer known as a proponent of anarchist communism.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Murray Bookchin</span> American social theorist (1921–2006)

Murray Bookchin was an American social theorist, author, orator, historian, and political philosopher. Influenced by G. W. F. Hegel, Karl Marx, Peter Kropotkin, he was a pioneer in the environmental movement. Bookchin formulated and developed the theory of social ecology and urban planning within anarchist, libertarian socialist, and ecological thought. He was the author of two dozen books covering topics in politics, philosophy, history, urban affairs, and social ecology. Among the most important were Our Synthetic Environment (1962), Post-Scarcity Anarchism (1971), The Ecology of Freedom (1982), and Urbanization Without Cities (1987). In the late 1990s, he became disenchanted with what he saw as an increasingly apolitical "lifestylism" of the contemporary anarchist movement, stopped referring to himself as an anarchist, and founded his own libertarian socialist ideology called "communalism", which seeks to reconcile and expand Marxist, syndicalist, and anarchist thought.

Anarchist economics is the set of theories and practices of economic activity within the political philosophy of anarchism. Many anarchists are anti-authoritarian and anti-capitalist, with anarchism usually referred to as a form of libertarian socialism, i.e. a stateless system of socialism. Anarchists support personal property and oppose capital concentration, interest, monopoly, private ownership of productive property such as the means of production, profit, rent, usury and wage slavery which are viewed as inherent to capitalism.

The nature of capitalism is criticized by left-wing anarchists, who reject hierarchy and advocate stateless societies based on non-hierarchical voluntary associations. Anarchism is generally defined as the libertarian philosophy which holds the state to be undesirable, unnecessary and harmful as well as opposing authoritarianism, illegitimate authority and hierarchical organization in the conduct of human relations. Capitalism is generally considered by scholars to be an economic system that includes private ownership of the means of production, creation of goods or services for profit or income, the accumulation of capital, competitive markets, voluntary exchange and wage labor, which have generally been opposed by most anarchists historically. Since capitalism is variously defined by sources and there is no general consensus among scholars on the definition nor on how the term should be used as a historical category, the designation is applied to a variety of historical cases, varying in time, geography, politics and culture.

Left-libertarianism, also known as left-wing libertarianism, or social libertarianism, is a political philosophy and type of libertarianism that stresses both individual freedom and social equality. Left-libertarianism represents several related yet distinct approaches to political and social theory. Its classical usage refers to anti-authoritarian varieties of left-wing politics such as anarchism, especially social anarchism, communalism, and libertarian Marxism, collectively termed libertarian socialism. A portion of the left wing of the green movement, including adherents of Murray Bookchin's social ecology, are also generally considered left-libertarian.

Libertarianism is a political philosophy that upholds liberty as a core value. Libertarians seek to maximize autonomy and political freedom, emphasizing equality before the law and civil rights to freedom of association, freedom of speech, freedom of thought and freedom of choice. Libertarians are often skeptical of or opposed to authority, state power, warfare, militarism and nationalism, but some libertarians diverge on the scope of their opposition to existing economic and political systems. Various schools of libertarian thought offer a range of views regarding the legitimate functions of state and private power. Different categorizations have been used to distinguish various forms of Libertarianism. Scholars distinguish libertarian views on the nature of property and capital, usually along left–right or socialist–capitalist lines. Libertarians of various schools were influenced by liberal ideas.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Libertarianism in the United States</span> Origin, history and development of libertarianism in the United States

In the United States, libertarianism is a political philosophy promoting individual liberty. According to common meanings of conservatism and liberalism in the United States, libertarianism has been described as conservative on economic issues and liberal on personal freedom, often associated with a foreign policy of non-interventionism. Broadly, there are four principal traditions within libertarianism, namely the libertarianism that developed in the mid-20th century out of the revival tradition of classical liberalism in the United States after liberalism associated with the New Deal; the libertarianism developed in the 1950s by anarcho-capitalist author Murray Rothbard, who based it on the anti-New Deal Old Right and 19th-century libertarianism and American individualist anarchists such as Benjamin Tucker and Lysander Spooner while rejecting the labor theory of value in favor of Austrian School economics and the subjective theory of value; the libertarianism developed in the 1970s by Robert Nozick and founded in American and European classical liberal traditions; and the libertarianism associated with the Libertarian Party, which was founded in 1971, including politicians such as David Nolan and Ron Paul.

Counter-economics is an economic theory and revolutionary method consisting of direct action carried out through the black market or the gray market. As a term, it was originally used by American libertarian activists and theorists Samuel Edward Konkin III and J. Neil Schulman. The former defined it as the study or practice "of all peaceful human action which is forbidden by the State".

Right-libertarianism, also known as libertarian capitalism, or right-wing libertarianism, is a libertarian political philosophy that supports capitalist property rights and defends market distribution of natural resources and private property. The term right-libertarianism is used to distinguish this class of views on the nature of property and capital from left-libertarianism, a type of libertarianism that combines self-ownership with an egalitarian approach to property and income. In contrast to socialist libertarianism, right-libertarianism supports free-market capitalism. Like most forms of libertarianism, it supports civil liberties, especially natural law, negative rights, the non-aggression principle, and a major reversal of the modern welfare state.

Anarchism is generally defined as the political philosophy which holds the state to be undesirable, unnecessary and harmful as well as opposing authority and hierarchical organization in the conduct of human relations. Proponents of anarchism, known as anarchists, advocate stateless societies based on non-hierarchical voluntary associations. While anarchism holds the state to be undesirable, unnecessary and harmful, opposition to the state is not its central or sole definition. Anarchism can entail opposing authority or hierarchy in the conduct of all human relations.

The following outline is provided as an overview of and topical guide to anarchism:

Types of socialism include a range of economic and social systems characterised by social ownership and democratic control of the means of production and organizational self-management of enterprises as well as the political theories and movements associated with socialism. Social ownership may refer to forms of public, collective or cooperative ownership, or to citizen ownership of equity in which surplus value goes to the working class and hence society as a whole. There are many varieties of socialism and no single definition encapsulates all of them, but social ownership is the common element shared by its various forms Socialists disagree about the degree to which social control or regulation of the economy is necessary, how far society should intervene, and whether government, particularly existing government, is the correct vehicle for change.

Market socialism is a type of economic system involving social ownership of the means of production within the framework of a market economy. Various models for such a system exist, usually involving cooperative enterprises and sometimes a mix that includes public or private enterprises. In contrast to the majority of historic socialist economies, which have substituted the market mechanism for some form of economic planning, market socialists wish to retain the use of supply and demand signals to guide the allocation of capital goods and the means of production. Under such a system, depending on whether socially owned firms are state-owned or operated as worker cooperatives, profits may variously be used to directly remunerate employees, accrue to society at large as the source of public finance, or be distributed amongst the population in a social dividend.

Anti-statism is any approach to social, economic or political philosophy that rejects statism. An anti-statist is one who opposes intervention by the state into personal, social and economic affairs. In anarchism, this is characterized by a complete rejection of all involuntary hierarchical rulership.

Anarchism and libertarianism, as broad political ideologies with manifold historical and contemporary meanings, have contested definitions. Their adherents have a pluralistic and overlapping tradition that makes precise definition of the political ideology difficult or impossible, compounded by a lack of common features, differing priorities of subgroups, lack of academic acceptance, and contentious historical usage.

References

  1. Definition of decentralisation. Merriam-Webster Dictionary. Archived from the original on 26 January 2013. Retrieved 5 March 2013.
  2. Vivien A. Schmidt, Democratizing France: The Political and Administrative History of Decentralization, Cambridge University Press, 2007, p. 22 Archived 2016-05-05 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0521036054
  3. Barbara Levick, Claudius, Psychology Press, 2012, p. 81 Archived 2016-06-02 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0415166195
  4. 1 2 Vivien A. Schmidt, Democratizing France: The Political and Administrative History of Decentralization, p. 10 Archived 2016-05-20 at the Wayback Machine .
  5. Robert Leroux, French Liberalism in the 19th Century: An Anthology, Chapter 6: Maurice Block on "Decentralization", Routledge, 2012, p. 255 Archived 2016-05-29 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-1136313011
  6. 1 2 3 A History of Decentralization Archived 2013-05-11 at the Wayback Machine , Earth Institute of Columbia University website, accessed February 4, 2013.
  7. George Edward Rines, ed. (1918). Encyclopedia Americana. New York: Encyclopedia Americana Corp. p. 624. OCLC   7308909.
  8. Hamilton, Peter (1995). Émile Durkheim. New York: Routledge. p. 79. ISBN   978-0415110471.
  9. "Du principe Fédératif" ("Principle of Federation"), 1863.
  10. Craig R. Prentiss, Debating God's Economy: Social Justice in America on the Eve of Vatican II, Penn State Press, 2008, p. 43 Archived 2016-05-03 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0271033419
  11. Kauffman, Bill (2008). "Decentralism". In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage, Cato Institute. pp. 111–113. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n71. ISBN   978-1412965804. LCCN   2008009151. OCLC   750831024. Archived from the original on 1 May 2016.
  12. David De Leon, Leaders from the 1960s: A Biographical Sourcebook of American Activism, Greenwood Publishing Group, 1994, p. 297 Archived 2015-11-05 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0313274145
  13. Nancy L. Roberts, Dorothy Day and the Catholic worker, Volume 84, Issue 1 of National security essay series, State University of New York Press, 1984, p. 11 Archived 2016-05-17 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0873959391
  14. Jesse Walker, Mark O. Hatfield, RIP Archived 2013-06-03 at the Wayback Machine , Reason, August 8, 2011.
  15. Mildred J. Loomis, Decentralism: Where It Came From – Where Is It Going?, Black Rose Books, 2005, ISBN   978-1551642499
  16. Bill Kauffman, Bye Bye, Miss American Empire: Neighborhood Patriots, Backcountry rebels, Chelsea Green Publishing, 2010, p. xxxi Archived 2016-05-05 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-1933392806
  17. Dr. Leopold Kohr, 84; Backed Smaller States Archived 2017-01-18 at the Wayback Machine , The New York Times obituary, February 28, 1994.
  18. John Fullerton, The Relevance of E. F. Schumacher in the 21st Century Archived 2013-04-05 at the Wayback Machine , New Economics Institute, accessed February 7, 2013.
  19. W. Patrick McCray, The Visioneers: How a Group of Elite Scientists Pursued Space Colonies, Nanotechnologies, and a Limitless Future, Princeton University Press, 2012, p. 70 Archived 2016-05-14 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0691139838
  20. Daniel Bell, The Coming Of Post-industrial Society, Basic Books version, 2008, p. 320–21 [ dead link ], ISBN   978-0786724734
  21. Alvin Toffler, Previews & Premises: An Interview with the Author of Future Shock and The Third Wave, Black Rose books, 1987, p. 50 Archived 2016-05-08 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0920057377
  22. John Naisbitt biography Archived 2013-09-16 at the Wayback Machine at personal website, accessed February 10, 2013.
  23. Sam Inkinen, Mediapolis: Aspects of Texts, Hypertexts and Multimedial Communication, Volume 25 of Research in Text Theory, Walter de Gruyter, 1999, p. 272 Archived 2016-04-28 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-3110807059
  24. Kamensky, John M. (May–June 1996). "Role of the "Reinventing Government" Movement in Federal Management Reform". Public Administration Review. 56 (3): 247–55. doi:10.2307/976448. JSTOR   976448.
  25. Stephen Cummings, ReCreating Strategy, SAGE, 2002, p. 157 Archived 2016-05-22 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0857026514
  26. Diana Conyers, "Decentralization: The latest fashion in development administration?" Archived 2014-05-22 at the Wayback Machine , Public Administration and Development, Volume 3, Issue 2, pp. 97–109, April/June 1983, via Wiley Online Library, accessed February 4, 2013.
  27. 1 2 3 4 Decentralization Archived 2012-10-26 at the Wayback Machine , article at the "Restructuring local government project Archived 2013-01-17 at the Wayback Machine " of Dr. Mildred Warner, Cornell University, accessed February 4, 2013.
  28. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions" (PDF). United Nations Development Programme. October 1999. pp. 11–12.
  29. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, p. 13.
  30. 1 2 Johnson, Norman L. (1999). "Diversity in Decentralized Systems: Enabling Self-Organizing Solutions". Theoretical Division, Los Alamos National Laboratory, for University of California Los Angeles 1999 conference "Decentralization Two". CiteSeerX   10.1.1.80.1110 .{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  31. PACE Project "What is Decentralization?" page Archived 2013-03-29 at the Wayback Machine , University of California, Irvine's Institute for Software Research, Last Updated – May 10, 2006.
  32. 1 2 Holger Daun, School Decentralization in the Context of Globalizing Governance: International Comparison of Grassroots Responses, Springer, 2007, pp. 28–29 Archived 2016-06-17 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-1402047008
  33. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, pp. 2, 16, 26.
  34. Subhabrata Dutta, Democratic decentralization and grassroot leadership in India Archived 2015-03-19 at the Wayback Machine , Mittal Publications, 2009, pp. 5–8, ISBN   978-8183242738
  35. Robert Charles Vipond, Liberty & Community: Canadian Federalism and the Failure of the Constitution Archived 2016-06-24 at the Wayback Machine , SUNY Press, 1991, p. 145, ISBN   978-0791404669
  36. Ribot, J (2003). "Democratic Decentralisation of Natural Resources: Institutional Choice and Discretionary Power Transfers in Sub-Saharan Africa". Public Administration and Development . 23: 53–65. doi:10.1002/pad.259. S2CID   55187335.
  37. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, pp. 12–13.
  38. 1 2 Political Decentralization Archived 2013-04-09 at the Wayback Machine , Decentralization and Subnational Economies project, World Bank website, accessed February 9, 2013.
  39. Therese A McCarty, Demographic diversity and the size of the public sector Archived 2014-05-22 at the Wayback Machine , Kyklos, 1993, via Wiley Online Library. Quote: "if demographic diversity promotes greater decentralization, the size of the public sector is not affected 10 consequently."
  40. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, p. 11.
  41. Jerry M. Silverman, Public Sector Decentralization: Economic Policy and Sector Investment Programs, Volume 188, World Bank Publications, 1992, p. 4 Archived 2016-05-28 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0821322796
  42. Don R. Hansen, Maryanne M. Mowen, Liming Guan, Cost Management: Accounting & Control, Cengage Learning, 2009, p. 338 Archived 2016-05-13 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0324559675
  43. David R. Cameron, Gustav Ranis, Annalisa Zinn, Globalization and Self-Determination: Is the Nation-State Under Siege?, Taylor & Francis, 2006, p. 203 Archived 2016-05-03 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0203086636
  44. Dawn Brancati, Peace by Design:Managing Intrastate Conflict through Decentralization, Oxford University Press, 2009, ISBN   978-0191615221
  45. 1 2 Ariunaa Lkhagvadorj, Fiscal federalism and decentralization in Mongolia, University of Potsdam, Germany, 2010, p. 23 Archived 2016-06-10 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-3869560533
  46. Karin E. Kemper, Ariel Dinar, Integrated River Basin Management Through Decentralization, Springer, 2007, p. 36 Archived 2016-04-25 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-3540283553.
  47. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, p. 12.
  48. Robert J. Taylor, Susan B. Taylor, The Aupha Manual of Health Services Management, Jones & Bartlett Learning, 1994, p. 33, ISBN   978-0834203631
  49. Frannie Frank Humplick, Azadeh Moini Araghi, "Is There an Optimal Structure for Decentralized Provision of Roads?", World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 1996, p. 35.
  50. Abbass F. Alkhafaji, Strategic Management: Formulation, Implementation, and Control in a Dynamic Environment, Psychology Press, 2003, p. 184, ISBN   978-0789018106
  51. Ehtisham Ahmad, Vito Tanzi, Managing Fiscal Decentralization, Routledge, 2003, p. 182 Archived 2016-05-27 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0203219997
  52. Aaron Tesfaye, Political Power and Ethnic Federalism: The Struggle for Democracy in Ethiopa, University Press of America, 2002, p. 44 Archived 2016-05-02 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0761822394
  53. Harry Ward Richardson, Urban economics, Dryden Press, 1978, pp. 107, 133, 159 Archived 2016-05-13 at the Wayback Machine .
  54. Allen G Noble, Frank J. Costa, Preserving the Legacy: Concepts in Support of Sustainability, Lexington Books, 1999, p. 214 Archived 2016-05-13 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0739100158
  55. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, p. 21.
  56. H.F.W. Dubois and G. Fattore, Definitions and typologies in public administration research: the case of decentralization, International Journal of Public Administration, Volume 32, Issue 8, 2009, pp. 704–27.
  57. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, p. 19.
  58. Cameron, David R.; Ranis, Gustav; Zinn, Annalisa (12 April 2006). Globalization and Self-Determination. Routledge. doi:10.4324/9780203086636. ISBN   978-0415770224.
  59. Henry Cabot Lodge, Volume 1 of The History of Nations, H. W. Snow, 1910, p. 164 Archived 2016-05-01 at the Wayback Machine .
  60. Stephen K. Sanderson, Civilizations and World Systems: Studying World-Historical Change, Rowman & Littlefield, 1995, pp. 118–19 Archived 2016-04-25 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0761991052
  61. Yildiz Atasoy, Hegemonic Transitions, the State and Crisis in Neoliberal Capitalism, Volume 7 of Routledge Studies in Governance and Change in the Global Era, Taylor & Francis US, 2009, pp. 65–67 Archived 2016-06-17 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0415473842
  62. Christopher K. Chase-Dunn, Thomas D. Hall, Rise and Demise: Comparing World Systems, Westview Press, 1997, pp. 20, 33 Archived 2016-05-17 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0813310060
  63. Editors: S. N. Mishra, Anil Dutta Mishra, Sweta Mishra, Public Governance and Decentralisation: Essays in Honour of T.N. Chaturvedi, Mittal Publications, 2003, p. 229 Archived 2016-05-01 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-8170999188
  64. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, pp. 5–8.
  65. Managing Decentralisation: A New Role for Labour Market Policy, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Local Economic and Employment Development (Program), OECD Publishing, 2003, p 135 Archived 2016-04-30 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-9264104709
  66. 1 2 3 4 5 Spina, Nicholas (July 2013). "Explaining political decentralization in parliamentary democracies". Comparative European Politics. 11 (4): 428–457. doi:10.1057/cep.2012.23. S2CID   144308683. ProQuest   1365933707.
  67. Treisman, Daniel (2007). The architecture of government: rethinking political decentralization. Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-0521872294.
  68. Rosenblatt, Fernando; Bidegain, Germán; Monestier, Felipe; Rodríguez, Rafael Piñeiro (2015). "A Natural Experiment in Political Decentralization: Local Institutions and Citizens' Political Engagement in Uruguay". Latin American Politics and Society. 57 (2): 91–110. doi:10.1111/j.1548-2456.2015.00268.x. S2CID   154689249.
  69. 1 2 Lyon, Aisling (2015). "Political decentralization and the strengthening of consensual, participatory local democracy in the Republic of Macedonia". Democratization. 22: 157–178. doi:10.1080/13510347.2013.834331. S2CID   145166616.
  70. 1 2 James, Manor (31 March 1999). "The political economy of democratic decentralization".
  71. 1 2 Somin, Ilya (2013). Democracy and Political Ignorance: Why Smaller Government is Smarter. ProQuest: Stanford University Press. ISBN   978-0804789318.
  72. Renko, Vappu; Johannisson, Jenny; Kangas, Anita; Blomgren, Roger (16 April 2022). "Pursuing decentralisation: regional cultural policies in Finland and Sweden". International Journal of Cultural Policy. 28 (3): 342–358. doi: 10.1080/10286632.2021.1941915 . ISSN   1028-6632.
  73. Fan, C. Simon; Lin, Chen; Treisman, Daniel (February 2009). "Political decentralization and corruption: Evidence from around the world". Journal of Public Economics. 93 (1–2): 14–34. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2008.09.001. hdl: 10722/192328 .
  74. 1 2 3 4 5 Different forms of decentralization Archived 2013-05-26 at the Wayback Machine , Earth Institute of Columbia University, accessed February 5, 2013.
  75. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, p. 8.
  76. By the way chosen by the Italian Supreme Court, the regional legislature is allowed to add its administrative penalties to national criminal punishment: Buonomo, Giampiero (2004). "Patrimonio dello Stato: le norme speciali e il taglio abusivo di bosco". Diritto&Giustizia Edizione Online. Archived from the original on 24 March 2016.
  77. Summary of Janet Kodras Archived 2012-06-16 at the Wayback Machine , "Restructuring the State: Devolution, Privatization, and the Geographic Redistribution of Power and Capacity in Governance", from State Devolution in America: Implications for a Diverse Society, Edited by Lynn Staeheli, Janet Kodras, and Colin Flint, Urban Affairs Annual Reviews 48, SAGE, 1997, pp. 79–68 at Restructuring local government project Archived 2013-01-17 at the Wayback Machine website.
  78. John Stossel, "Private charity would do much more – if government hadn't crowded it out Archived 2013-02-09 at the Wayback Machine ", Jewish World Review, August 24, 2005.
  79. David King, Fiscal Tiers: The Economics of Multilevel Government, George Allen and Unwin, 1984.
  80. Nico Groenendijk, "Fiscal federalism Revisited" paper presented at Institutions in Transition Conference organized by IMAD, Slovenia Ljublijana.
  81. "Decentralization: A Sampling of Definitions", 1999, p. 18.
  82. Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations Archived 2013-06-16 at the Wayback Machine , Decentralization and Subnational Economies project, World Bank website, accessed February 9, 2013.
  83. Winston, Clifford (1998). "US industry adjustment to economic deregulation". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 12 (3): 89–110. doi: 10.1257/jep.12.3.89 .
  84. Jerry Taylor and Peter Van Doren, Short-Circuited Archived 2013-06-17 at the Wayback Machine , The Wall Street Journal, August 30, 2007, reprinted at Cato Institute website.
  85. Calabria, Mark A. (2009). "Did Deregulation Cause the Financial Crisis?". CATO Institute.
  86. "485 K.P.Kannan, People's planning, Kerala's dilemma". Archived from the original on 29 April 2015.
  87. Auriol, Emmanuelle; Benaim, Michel (1 June 2000). "Standardization in Decentralized Economies" (PDF). American Economic Review. 90 (3): 550–570. doi:10.1257/aer.90.3.550. Archived (PDF) from the original on 21 July 2018.
  88. Smith, Vernon L.; Simmons, Emily (9 December 1999). "How and Why to Privatize Federal Lands". CATO Institute.
  89. Larson, Anne M. (August 2003). "Decentralisation and forest management in Latin America: towards a working model". Public Administration and Development. 23 (3): 211–226. doi:10.1002/pad.271. S2CID   39722511.
  90. Ribot, J (2002). Democratic Decentralisation of Natural Resources: Institutionalising Popular Participation. Oxon: Routledge.[ page needed ]
  91. I. Scoones, Beyond Farmer First, London: Intermediate technology publications.
  92. Larson, Anne M (January 2002). "Natural Resources and Decentralization in Nicaragua: Are Local Governments Up to the Job?". World Development. 30 (1): 17–31. doi:10.1016/s0305-750x(01)00098-5.
  93. Binkley, Robert C. Realism and Nationalism 1852–1871. Read Books. p. 118
  94. "The revolution abolishes private ownership of the means of production and distribution, and with it goes capitalistic business. Personal possession remains only in the things you use. Thus, your watch is your own, but the watch factory belongs to the people." Archived 23 May 2012 at the Wayback Machine Alexander Berkman. "What Is Communist Anarchism?" What is Communist Anarchism?. Archived from the original on 23 May 2012. Retrieved 5 September 2017.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  95. As Noam Chomsky put it, a consistent libertarian "must oppose private ownership of the means of production and the wage slavery, which is a component of this system, as incompatible with the principle that labor must be freely undertaken and under the control of the producer". Chomsky (2003) p. 26 Archived 2016-05-05 at the Wayback Machine
  96. Paul Zarembka. Transitions in Latin America and in Poland and Syria. Emerald Group Publishing, 2007. p. 25
  97. Guerin, Daniel. Anarchism: A Matter of Words: "Some contemporary anarchists have tried to clear up the misunderstanding by adopting a more explicit term: they align themselves with libertarian socialism or communism." Faatz, Chris, Towards a Libertarian Socialism.
  98. Ostergaard, Geoffrey. "Anarchism". A Dictionary of Marxist Thought. Blackwell Publishing, 1991. p. 21.
  99. Chomsky (2004) p. 739
  100. Ross, Jeffery Ian. Controlling State Crime Archived 2015-03-18 at the Wayback Machine , Transaction Publishers (2000) p. 400 ISBN   0-7658-0695-9
  101. Ackelsberg, Martha A. (2005). Free Women of Spain: Anarchism and the Struggle for the Emancipation of Women . AK Press. p. 41. ISBN   978-1902593968.
  102. Rocker, Rudolf (2004). Anarcho-Syndicalism: Theory and Practice. AK Press. p. 65. ISBN   978-1902593920.
  103. Spiegel, Henry. The Growth of Economic Thought Duke University Press (1991) p. 446
  104. Paul, Ellen Frankel et al. Problems of Market Liberalism Cambridge University Press (1998) p. 305
  105. However, libertarian socialism retains respect for personal property.
  106. Sims, Franwa (2006). The Anacostia Diaries As It Is. Lulu Press. p. 160.
  107. A Mutualist FAQ: A.4. Are Mutualists Socialists? Archived 2009-06-09 at the Wayback Machine . Mutualist.org. Retrieved on 2011-12-28.
  108. Murray Bookchin, Ghost of Anarcho-Syndicalism; Robert Graham, The General Idea of Proudhon's Revolution
  109. Kent Bromley, in his preface to Peter Kropotkin's book The Conquest of Bread , considered early French utopian socialist Charles Fourier to be the founder of the libertarian branch of socialist thought, as opposed to the authoritarian socialist ideas of Babeuf and Buonarroti." Kropotkin, Peter. The Conquest of Bread, preface by Kent Bromley, New York and London, G. P. Putnam's Sons, 1906.
  110. "(Benjamin) Tucker referred to himself many times as a socialist and considered his philosophy to be "Anarchistic socialism." An Anarchist FAQ by Various Authors
  111. French individualist anarchist Émile Armand shows clearly opposition to capitalism and centralized economies when he said that the individualist anarchist "inwardly he remains refractory – fatally refractory – morally, intellectually, economically (The capitalist economy and the directed economy, the speculators and the fabricators of single are equally repugnant to him.)""Anarchist Individualism as a Life and Activity" by Emile Armand Archived 2012-07-28 at the Wayback Machine
  112. Anarchist Peter Sabatini reports that In the United States "of early to mid-19th century, there appeared an array of communal and "utopian" counterculture groups (including the so-called free love movement). William Godwin's anarchism exerted an ideological influence on some of this, but more so the socialism of Robert Owen and Charles Fourier. After success of his British venture, Owen himself established a cooperative community within the United States at New Harmony, Indiana during 1825. One member of this commune was Josiah Warren (1798–1874), considered to be the first individualist anarchist"Peter Sabatini. "Libertarianism: Bogus Anarchy" Archived 2012-05-03 at the Wayback Machine
  113. Lewis Herber. (Murray Bookchin) "Ecology and Revolutionary Thought" Archived 2012-05-15 at the Wayback Machine . Theanarchistlibrary.org (2009-04-27). Retrieved on 2011-12-28.
  114. 1 2 3 "Anarchism". In Our Time . BBC Radio 4. 7 December 2006. Archived from the original on 28 March 2012. Retrieved 30 April 2012.
  115. Sheehan, Sean. Anarchism, London: Reaktion Books, 2004. p. 85.
  116. Guerin, Daniel (ed.) No Gods, No Masters, AK Press, vol. 1, p. 62
  117. The General Idea of the Revolution, Pluto Press, pp. 277, 281
  118. "Anarchist Communism: Its Basis and Principles". marxists.org. 4 December 2023. Archived from the original on 12 August 2023.
  119. George Woodcock. Anarchism: a history of libertarian movements. p. 357
  120. George Woodcock. Anarchism: a history of libertarian movements. p. 357
  121. "Anarchism" Archived 2014-04-24 at the Wayback Machine at the Encyclopædia Britannica online.
  122. "This process of education and class organization, more than any single factor in Spain, produced the collectives. And to the degree that the CNT-FAI (for the two organizations became fatally coupled after July 1936) exercised the major influence in an area, the collectives proved to be generally more durable, communist and resistant to Stalinist counterrevolution than other republican-held areas of Spain." Murray Bookchin Archived 23 October 2021 at the Wayback Machine . To Remember Spain: The Anarchist and Syndicalist Revolution of 1936
  123. "To Remember Spain: The Anarchist and Syndicalist Revolution of 1936". Archived from the original on 18 March 2012 via www.theanarchistlibrary.org.
  124. 1 2 Noam Chomsky Notes on Anarchism Archived 2014-08-28 at the Wayback Machine
  125. Marvin Victor Zelkowitz, Editor, Advances in Computers, Volume 82, Academic Press, 2011, p. 3 Archived 2016-05-28 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0123855138
  126. Eleanor Doyle, The Economic System, John Wiley & Sons, 2005, p. 61 Archived 2016-06-23 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0470015179
  127. Friedrich von Hayek, The Road to Serfdom: Text and documents – the definitive edition; Volume 2 of Collected Works of F. A. Hayek, edited by Bruce Caldwell, University of Chicago Press, 2009, p. 94 Archived 2016-05-15 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0226320533
  128. Bruce M. Owen, Antecedents to Net Neutrality Archived 2013-06-17 at the Wayback Machine , Cato Institute publication "Regulation", Fall, 2007, p. 16.
  129. Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservatism: A Reinterpretation of American History, 1900–1916, Chapter Two: "Competition and Decentralization: The Failure to Rationalize Industry", Simon and Schuster, 2008, pp. 26–56, 141, 220, 243, 351 Archived 2016-05-11 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-1439118726
  130. Roy Childs, "Big Business and the Rise of American Statism Archived 2013-01-30 at the Wayback Machine ", Reason, 1971.
  131. D. T. Armentano, Antitrust Policy: Reform or Repeal? Archived 2013-06-17 at the Wayback Machine , Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 21, January 18, 1983
  132. John Montgomery, The New Wealth of Cities: City Dynamics and the Fifth Wave, Ashgate Publishing, Ltd., 2008, p. 2 Archived 2016-05-22 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0754674153
  133. Jane Jacobs, The Question of Separatism: Quebec and the Struggle over Sovereignty, (1980 Random House and 2011 Baraka Books), ISBN   978-1926824062
  134. Gopal Balakrishnan, Mapping the Nation, Verso, 1996, p. 277 Archived 2016-06-10 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-1859840603
  135. Jacobs, Jane (1984). Cities and the Wealth of Nations: Principles of Economic Life. Vintage Books. ISBN   0-394-72911-0.
  136. Perloff, Jeffrey M. (2018). Microeconomics (8th ed.). New York, NY. ISBN   978-0-13-451953-1. OCLC   966436503.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)[ page needed ]
  137. Ouchi, William G. (April 2006). "Power to the Principals: Decentralization in Three Large School Districts". Organization Science. 17 (2): 298–307. doi:10.1287/orsc.1050.0172.
  138. Zábojník, Ján (January 2002). "Centralized and Decentralized Decision Making in Organizations". Journal of Labor Economics. 20 (1): 1–22. doi:10.1086/323929. S2CID   222328856.
  139. Aghion, P.; Bloom, N.; Van Reenen, J. (1 May 2014). "Incomplete Contracts and the Internal Organization of Firms". Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. 30 (suppl 1): i37–i63. doi:10.1093/jleo/ewt003.
  140. Aghion, Philippe; Bloom, Nicholas; Lucking, Brian; Sadun, Raffaella; Van Reenen, John (1 January 2021). "Turbulence, Firm Decentralization, and Growth in Bad Times". American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 13 (1): 133–169. doi:10.1257/app.20180752. hdl: 10419/161329 . S2CID   234358121.
  141. Leiponen, Aija; Helfat, Constance E. (June 2011). "Location, Decentralization, and Knowledge Sources for Innovation". Organization Science. 22 (3): 641–658. doi:10.1287/orsc.1100.0526.
  142. Schilling, Melissa A. (2017). Strategic management of technological innovation (5th ed.). New York, NY. ISBN   978-1-259-53906-0. OCLC   929155407.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  143. Bucic, Tania; Gudergan, Siegfried P. (2004). "The Impact of Organizational Settings on Creativity and Learning in Alliances". M@n@gement. 7 (3): 257–273. doi:10.3917/mana.073.0257. hdl: 10453/5995 .
  144. Foss, Nicolai J.; Laursen, Keld; Pedersen, Torben (August 2011). "Linking Customer Interaction and Innovation: The Mediating Role of New Organizational Practices". Organization Science. 22 (4): 980–999. doi: 10.1287/orsc.1100.0584 .
  145. Burton, M. Diane; Colombo, Massimo G.; Rossi-Lamastra, Cristina; Wasserman, Noam (September 2019). "The organizational design of entrepreneurial ventures". Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal. 13 (3): 243–255. doi:10.1002/sej.1332. S2CID   201351323.
  146. Eggimann, S. The optimal degree of centralisation for wastewater infrastructures. A model-based geospatial economic analysis Doctoral Thesis ETH Zurich., 30. November 2016.
  147. Jeremy Magliaro, Amory Lovins, Valuing Decentralized Wastewater Technologies: A Catalog of Benefits, Costs, and Economic Analysis Techniques Archived 2013-03-05 at the Wayback Machine , Rocky Mountain Institute, 2004.
  148. Lawrence D. Smith, Reform and Decentralization of Agricultural Services: A Policy Framework, United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization, 2001, p. 2010–211 Archived 2016-06-10 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-9251046449
  149. Lawrence D. Smith, Reform and Decentralization of Agricultural Services: A Policy Framework, 2001.
  150. Maggie Koerth-Baker, What We Talk About When We Talk About the Decentralization of Energy Archived 2016-12-31 at the Wayback Machine , The Atlantic, April 16, 2012.
  151. "How blockchain technology could electrify the energy industry". www.theneweconomy.com. Retrieved 7 October 2019.
  152. Fred E. Foldvary, Daniel Bruce Klein, Editors, The Half-Life of Policy Rationales: How New Technology Affects Old Policy Issues NYU Press, 2003, pp. 1, 184 Archived 2016-05-01 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0814747773
  153. Eggimann, Sven; Truffer, Bernhard; Maurer, Max (November 2015). "To connect or not to connect? Modelling the optimal degree of centralisation for wastewater infrastructures". Water Research. 84: 218–231. Bibcode:2015WatRe..84..218E. doi:10.1016/j.watres.2015.07.004. PMID   26247101.
  154. Chandler, Daniel; Munday, Rod (January 2011), "Information technology", A Dictionary of Media and Communication (first ed.), Oxford University Press, ISBN   978-0-19-956875-8 , retrieved 1 August 2012(subscription required)
  155. John Baschab, Jon Piot, The Executive's Guide to Information Technology, John Wiley & Sons, 2007, p. 119 Archived 2016-05-01 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0470135914
  156. G. David Garson, Modern Public Information Technology Systems: Issues and Challenges, IGI Global, 2007, p. 115–20 Archived 2016-05-19 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-1599040530
  157. 1 2 3 Kopfstein, Janus (12 December 2013). "The Mission To Decentralize The Internet". The New Yorker. Condé Nast. Archived from the original on 13 December 2013. Retrieved 13 December 2013.
  158. Thomas W. Malone, Robert Laubacher, Michael S. Scott Morton, Inventing Organizations 21st Century, MIT Press, 2003, 65–66 Archived 2016-04-28 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0262632737
  159. Chris DiBona, Mark Stone, Danese Cooper, Open Sources 2.0: The Continuing Evolution, O'Reilly Media, Inc., 2008, p. 316 Archived 2016-06-10 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0596553890
  160. Axel Bruns, Blogs, Wikipedia, Second Life, and Beyond: From Production to Produsage, Peter Lang, 2008, p. 80 Archived 2016-05-28 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-0820488660
  161. Joseph Nye, The politics of the information age Archived 2013-02-21 at the Wayback Machine , Prague Post, February 13, 2010.
  162. Adi Kamdar and Peter Eckersley, Can the FCC Create Public "Super WiFi Networks"? Archived 2013-02-12 at the Wayback Machine , Electronic Frontier Foundation, February 5, 2013.
  163. Jennifer Holt, Alisa Perren, Media Industries: History, Theory, and Method, John Wiley & Sons, 2011, pp. 1995–97 Archived 2016-05-04 at the Wayback Machine , ISBN   978-1444360233
  164. David G. Post and David R. Johnson, 'Chaos Prevailing on Every Continent': Towards a New Theory of Decentralized Decision-Making in Complex Systems Archived 2011-08-26 at the Wayback Machine , Chicago-Kent Law Review, Vol. 73, No. 4, p. 1055, 1998, full version at David G. Post's Temple University website Archived 2012-10-03 at the Wayback Machine .
  165. Pandl, Konstantin D.; Thiebes, Scott; Schmidt-Kraepelin, Manuel; Sunyaev, Ali (2020). "On the Convergence of Artificial Intelligence and Distributed Ledger Technology: A Scoping Review and Future Research Agenda". IEEE Access. 8: 57075–57095. arXiv: 2001.11017 . doi: 10.1109/ACCESS.2020.2981447 . ISSN   2169-3536.
  166. Bolychevsky, Irina (12 November 2013). "BBC Radio Five Live". Outriders (Interview). Interviewed by Jamillah Knowles. Archived from the original on 15 December 2013. Retrieved 12 December 2013.
  167. Anderson, Mally (7 February 2019). "Exploring Decentralization: Blockchain Technology and Complex Coordination". Journal of Design and Science.
  168. Chen, Yan; Bellavitis, Cristiano (1 June 2020). "Blockchain disruption and decentralized finance: The rise of decentralized business models". Journal of Business Venturing Insights. 13: e00151. doi:10.1016/j.jbvi.2019.e00151. ISSN   2352-6734.
  169. Christina Ovezik, Dimitris Karakostas and Aggelos Kiayia, "SoK: a stratified approach to blockchain decentralization", Financial Cryptography and Data Security 2024, 4–8 March 2024, https://fc24.ifca.ai/preproceedings/227.pdf
  170. Zarrin, Javad; Wen Phang, Hao; Babu Saheer, Lakshmi; Zarrin, Bahram (December 2021). "Blockchain for decentralization of internet: prospects, trends, and challenges". Cluster Computing. 24 (4): 2841–2866. doi:10.1007/s10586-021-03301-8. PMC   8122205 . PMID   34025209.
  171. Gururaj, H. L.; Manoj Athreya, A.; Kumar, Ashwin A.; Holla, Abhishek M.; Nagarajath, S. M.; Ravi Kumar, V. (2020). "Blockchain". Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain Technology Applications. pp. 1–24. doi:10.1002/9781119621201.ch1. ISBN   9781119621164. S2CID   242394449.
  172. Wright, Aaron; De Filippi, Primavera (10 March 2015). "Decentralized Blockchain Technology and the Rise of Lex Cryptographia". doi:10.2139/ssrn.2580664. SSRN   2580664.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  173. McGinnis, John; Roche, Kyle (October 2019). "Bitcoin: Order Without Law in the Digital Age". Indiana Law Journal. 94 (4): 6.
  174. Hazeltine, B.; Bull, C. (1999). Appropriate Technology: Tools, Choices, and Implications. New York: Academic Press. pp. 3, 270. ISBN   978-0123351906.
  175. Litvack Ilene, Jennie; Seddon, Jessica (1999). Decentralization briefing notes. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute. Archived from the original on 30 September 2022. Retrieved 30 September 2022.
  176. Chapter 2. Decentralization and environmental issues Archived 2013-01-02 at the Wayback Machine , "Environment in decentralized development", United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization ("FAO"), accessed February 23, 2013; also see Environment in Decentralized Decision Making, An Overview Archived 2013-05-29 at the Wayback Machine , Agricultural Policy Support Service, Policy Assistance Division, FAO, Rome, Italy, November 2005.
  177. Summary of Remy Prud’homme, "The Dangers of Decentralization Archived 2012-06-16 at the Wayback Machine ", World Bank Research Observer, 10(2):201, 1995, linked from Decentralization Archived 2012-10-26 at the Wayback Machine , article "Restructuring local government project" of Dr. Mildred Warner.

Further reading